|
5: Reparation
<< 4: The Treaty || 6: Europe After the Treaty >>
I. Undertakings Given Pride to the Peace Negotiations
The categories of damage in respect of which the Allies were
entitled to ask for reparation are governed by the relevant
passages in President Wilson's Fourteen Points of 8 January 1918,
as modified by the Allied governments in their qualifying Note,
the text of which the President formally communicated to the
German government as the basis of peace on 5 November 1918. These
passages have been quoted in full at the beginning of chapter 4.
That is to say, 'compensation will be made by Germany for all
damage done to the civilian population of the Allies and to their
property by the aggression of Germany by land, by sea, and from
the air.' The limiting quality of this sentence is reinforced by
the passage in the President's speech before Congress on 11
February 1918 (the terms of this speech being an express part of
the contract with the enemy), that there shall be 'no
contributions' and 'no punitive damages'.
It has sometimes been argued that the preamble to paragraph
19(1*) of the armistice terms, to the effect 'that any future
claims and demands of the Allies and the United States of America
remain unaffected,' wiped out all precedent conditions, and left
the Allies free to make whatever demands they chose. But it is
not possible to maintain that this casual protective phrase, to
which no one at the time attached any particular importance, did
away with all the formal communications which passed between the
President and the German government as to the basis of the terms
of peace during the days preceding the armistice, abolished the
Fourteen Points, and converted the German acceptance of the
armistice terms into unconditional surrender, so far as affects
the financial clauses. It is merely the usual phrase of the
draftsman who, about to rehearse a list of certain claims, wishes
to guard himself from the implication that such a list is
exhaustive. In any case this contention is disposed of by the
Allied reply to the German observations on the first draft of the
treaty, where it is admitted that the terms of the reparation
chapter must be governed by the President's Note of 5 November.
Assuming then that the terms of this Note are binding, we are
left to elucidate the precise force of the phrase -- 'all damage
done to the civilian population of the Allies and to their
property by the aggression of Germany by land, by sea, and from
the air'. Few sentences in history have given so much work to the
sophists and the lawyers, as we shall see in the next section of
this chapter, as this apparently simple and unambiguous
statement. Some have not scrupled to argue that it covers the
entire cost of the war; for, they point out, the entire cost of
the war has to be met by taxation, and such taxation is 'damaging
to the civilian population'. They admit that the phrase is
cumbrous, and that it would have been simpler to have said 'all
loss and expenditure of whatever description'; and they allow
that the apparent emphasis on damage to the persons and property
of civilians is unfortunate; but errors of draftsmanship should
not, in their opinion, shut off the Allies from the rights
inherent in victors.
But there are not only the limitations of the phrase in its
natural meaning and the emphasis on civilian damages as distinct
from military expenditure generally; it must also be remembered
that the context of the term is in elucidation of the meaning of
the term 'restoration' in the President's Fourteen Points. The
Fourteen Points provide for damage in invaded territory --
Belgium, France, Roumania, Serbia, and Montenegro (Italy being
unaccountably omitted) -- but they do not cover losses at sea by
submarine, bombardments from the sea (as at Scarborough), or
damage done by air raids. It was to repair these omissions, which
involved losses to the life and property of civilians not really
distinguishable in kind from those effected in occupied
territory, that the Supreme Council of the Allies in Paris
proposed to President Wilson their qualifications. At that time
-- the last days of October 1918 -- I do not believe that any
responsible statesman had in mind the exaction from Germany of an
indemnity for the general costs of the war. They sought only to
make it clear (a point of considerable importance to Great
Britain) that reparation for damage done to non-combatants and
their property was not limited to invaded territory (as it would
have been by the Fourteen Points unqualified), but applied
equally to all such damage, whether 'by land, by sea, or from the
air'. It was only at a later stage that a general popular demand
for an indemnity, covering the full costs of the war, made it
politically desirable to practise dishonesty and to try to
discover in the written word what was not there.
What damages, then, can be claimed from the enemy on a strict
interpretation of our engagements?(2*) In the case of the United
Kingdom the bill would cover the following items --
- Damage to civilian life and property by the acts of an
enemy government, including damage by air raids, naval
bombardments, submarine warfare, and mines.
- Compensation for improper treatment of interned
civilians.
It would not include the general costs of the war or (e.g.)
indirect damage due to loss of trade.
The French claim would include, as well as items
corresponding to the above --
- Damage done to the property and persons of civilians in
the war area, and by aerial warfare behind the enemy lines.
- Compensation for loot of food, raw materials, livestock,
machinery, household effects, timber, and the like by the enemy
governments or their nationals in territory occupied by them.
- Repayment of fines and requisitions levied by the enemy
governments or their officers on French municipalities or
nationals.
- Compensation to French nationals deported or compelled to
do forced labour.
In addition to the above there is a further item of more
doubtful character, namely --
- The expenses of the relief commission in providing
necessary food and clothing to maintain the civilian French
population in the enemy-occupied districts.
The Belgian claim would include similar items.(3*) If it were
argued that in the case of Belgium something more nearly
resembling an indemnity for general war costs can be justified,
this could only be on the ground of the breach of international
law involved in the invasion of Belgium, whereas, as we have
seen, the Fourteen Points include no special demands on this
ground.(4*) As the cost of Belgian relief under (g), as well as
her general war costs, has been met already by advances from the
British, French, and United States governments, Belgium would
presumably employ any repayment of them by Germany in part
discharge of her debt to these governments, so that any such
demands are, in effect, an addition to the claims of the three
lending governments.
The claims of the other Allies would be compiled on similar
lines. But in their case the question arises more acutely how far
Germany can be made contingently liable for damage done, not by
herself, but by her co-belligerents, Austria-Hungary, Bulgaria,
and Turkey. This is one of the many questions to which the
Fourteen Points give no clear answer; on the one hand, they cover
explicitly in point II damage done to Roumania, Serbia, and
Montenegro, without qualification as to the nationality of the
troops inflicting the damage; on the other hand, the Note of the
Allies speaks of 'German' aggression when it might have spoken of
the aggression of 'Germany and her allies'. On a strict and
literal interpretation, I doubt if claims lie against Germany for
damage done, e.g. by the Turks to the Suez Canal, or by Austrian
submarines in the Adriatic. But it is a case where, if the Allies
wished to strain a point, they could impose contingent liability
on Germany without running seriously contrary to the general
intention of their engagements.
As between the Allies themselves the case is quite different.
It would be an act of gross unfairness and infidelity if France
and Great Britain were to take what Germany could pay and leave
Italy and Serbia to get what they could out of the remains of
Austria-Hungary. As amongst the Allies themselves it is clear
that assets should be pooled and shared out in proportion to
aggregate claims.
In this event, and if my estimate is accepted, as given
below, that Germany's capacity to pay will be exhausted by the
direct and legitimate claims which the Allies hold against her,
the question of her contingent liability for her allies becomes
academic. Prudent and honourable statesmanship would therefore
have given her the benefit of the doubt, and claimed against her
nothing but the damage she had herself caused.
What, on the above basis of claims, would the aggregate
demand amount to? No figures exist on which to base any
scientific or exact estimate, and I give my own guess for what it
is worth, prefacing it with the following observations.
The amount of the material damage done in the invaded
districts has been the subject of enormous, if natural,
exaggeration. A journey through the devastated areas of France is
impressive to the eye and the imagination beyond description.
During the winter of 1918-19, before Nature had cast over the
scene her ameliorating mantle, the horror and desolation of war
was made visible to sight on an extraordinary scale of blasted
grandeur. The completeness of the destruction was evident. For
mile after mile nothing was left. No building was habitable and
no field fit for the plough. The sameness was also striking. One
devastated area was exactly like another -- a heap of rubble, a
morass of shell-holes, and a tangle of wire.(5*) The amount of
human labour which would be required to restore such a
countryside seemed incalculable; and to the returned traveller
any number of milliards of pounds was inadequate to express in
matter the destruction thus impressed upon his spirit. Some
governments for a variety of intelligible reasons have not been
ashamed to exploit these feelings a little.
Popular sentiment is most at fault, I think, in the case of
Belgium. In any event Belgium is a small country, and in its case
the actual area of devastation is a small proportion of the
whole. The first onrush of the Germans in 1914 did some damage
locally; after that the battle-line in Belgium did not sway
backwards and forwards, as in France, over a deep belt of
country. It was practically stationary, and hostilities were
confined to a small corner of the country, much of which in
recent times was backward, poor, and sleepy, and did not include
the active industry of the country. There remains some injury in
the small flooded area, the deliberate damage done by the
retreating Germans to buildings, plant, and transport, and the
loot of machinery, cattle, and other movable property. But
Brussels, Antwerp, and even Ostend are substantially intact, and
the great bulk of the land, which is Belgium's chief wealth, is
nearly as well cultivated as before. The traveller by motor can
pass through and from end to end of the devastated area of
Belgium almost before he knows it; whereas the destruction in
France is on a different kind of scale altogether. Industrially,
the loot has been serious and for the moment paralysing; but the
actual money cost of replacing machinery mounts up slowly, and a
very few tens of millions would have covered the value of every
machine of every possible description that Belgium ever
possessed. Besides, the cold statistician must not overlook the
fact that the Belgian people possess the instinct of individual
self-protection unusually well developed; and the great mass of
German bank-notes(6*) held in the country at the date of the
armistice shows that certain classes of them at least found a
way, in spite of all the severities and barbarities of German
rule, to profit at the expense of the invader. Belgian claims
against Germany such as I have seen, amounting to a sum in excess
of the total estimated pre-war wealth of the whole country, are
simply irresponsible.(7*)
It will help to guide our ideas to quote the official survey
of Belgian wealth published in 1913 by the Finance Ministry of
Belgium, which was as follows:
Million £
Land 264
Buildings 235
Personal wealth 545
Cash 17
Furniture, etc. 120
Total 1,181
This total yields an average of £156 per inhabitant, which Dr
Stamp, the highest authority on the subject, is disposed to
consider as prima facie too low (though he does not accept
certain much higher estimates lately current), the corresponding
wealth per head (to take Belgium's immediate neighbours) being
£167 for Holland, £244 for Germany, and £303 for France.(8*) A
total of £1,500 million, giving an average of about £200 per
head, would, however, be fairly liberal. The official estimate of
land and buildings is likely to be more accurate than the rest.
On the other hand, allowance has to be made for the increased
costs of construction.
Having regard to all these considerations, I do not put the
money value of the actual physical loss of Belgian property by
destruction and loot above £150 million as a maximum, and while I
hesitate to put yet lower an estimate which differs so widely
from those generally current, I shall be surprised if it proves
possible to substantiate claims even to this amount. Claims in
respect of levies, fines, requisitions, and so forth might
possibly amount to a further £100 million. If the sums advanced
to Belgium by her allies for the general costs of the war are to
be included, a sum of about £250 million has to be added (which
includes the cost of relief), bringing the total to £500 million.
The destruction in France was on an altogether more
significant scale, not only as regards the length of the
battle-line, but also on account of the immensely deeper area of
country over which the battle swayed from time to time. It is a
popular delusion to think of Belgium as the principal victim of
the war; it will turn out, I believe, that taking account of
casualties, loss of property, and burden of future debt, Belgium
has made the least relative sacrifice of all the belligerents
except the United States. Of the Allies, Serbia's sufferings and
loss have been proportionately the greatest, and after Serbia,
France. France in all essentials was just as much the victim of
German ambition as was Belgium, and France's entry into the war
was just as unavoidable. France, in my judgment, in spite of her
policy at the peace conference, a policy largely traceable to her
sufferings, has the greatest claims on our generosity.
The special position occupied by Belgium in the popular mind
is due, of course, to the fact that in 1914 her sacrifice was by
far the greatest of any of the Allies. But after 1914 she played
a minor role. Consequently, by the end of 1918, her relative
sacrifices, apart from those sufferings from invasion which
cannot be measured in money, had fallen behind, and in some
respects they were not even as great as, for example,
Australia's. I say this with no wish to evade the obligations
towards Belgium under which the pronouncements of our responsible
statesmen at many different dates have certainly laid us. Great
Britain ought not to seek any payment at all from Germany for
herself until the just claims of Belgium have been fully
satisfied. But this is no reason why we or they should not tell
the truth about the amount.
While the French claims are immensely greater, here too there
has been excessive exaggeration, as responsible French
statisticians have themselves pointed out. Not above 10% of the
area of France was effectively occupied by the enemy, and not
above 4% lay within the area of substantial devastation. Of the
sixty French towns having a population exceeding 35,000, only two
were destroyed -- Reims (115,178) and St. Quentin (55,571); three
others were occupied -- Lille, Roubaix, and Douai -- and suffered
from loot of machinery and other property, but were not
substantially injured otherwise. Amiens, Calais, Dunkerque, and
Boulogne suffered secondary damage by bombardment and from the
air; but the value of Calais and Boulogne must have been
increased by the new works of various kinds erected for the use
of the British army.
The Annuaire statistique de la France, 1917, values the
entire house property of France at £2,380 million (59.5 milliard
francs).(9*) An estimate current in France of £800 million (20
milliard francs) for the destruction of house property alone is,
therefore, obviously wide of the mark.(10*) £120 million at
pre-war prices, or say £250 million at the present time, is much
nearer the right figure. Estimates of the value of the land of
France (apart from buildings) vary from £2,480 million to £3,116
million, so that it would be extravagant to put the damage on
this head as high as £100 million. Farm capital for the whole of
France has not been put by responsible authorities above £420
million.(11*) There remain the loss of furniture and machinery,
the damage to the coal-mines and the transport system, and many
other minor items. But these losses, however serious, cannot be
reckoned in value by hundreds of millions sterling in respect of
so small a part of France. In short, it will be difficult to
establish a bill exceeding £500 million, for physical and
material damage in the occupied and devastated areas of northern
France.(12*) I am confirmed in this estimate by the opinion of M.
René Pupin, the author of the most comprehensive and scientific
estimate of the pre-war wealth of France,(13*) which I did not
come across until after my own figure had been arrived at. This
authority estimates the material losses of the invaded regions at
from £400 million to £600 million (10 to 15 milliards),(14*)
between which my own figure falls half-way.
Nevertheless, M. Dubois, speaking on behalf of the budget
commission of the Chamber, has given the figure of £2,600 million
(65 milliard francs) 'as a minimum' without counting 'war levies,
losses at sea, the roads, or the loss of public monuments'. And
M. Loucheur, the Minister of Industrial Reconstruction, stated
before the Senate on 17 February 1919 that the reconstitution of
the devastated regions would involve an expenditure of £3,000
million (75 milliard francs) -- more than double M. Pupin's
estimate of the entire wealth of their inhabitants. But then at
that time M. Loucheur was taking a prominent part in advocating
the claims of France before the peace conference, and, like
others, may have found strict veracity inconsistent with the
demands of patriotism.(15*)
The figure discussed so far is not, however, the totality of
the French claims. There remain, in particular, levies and
requisitions on the occupied areas and the losses of the French
mercantile marine at sea from the attacks of German cruisers and
submarines. Probably £200 million would be ample to cover all
such claims. but to be on the safe side, we will, somewhat
arbitrarily, make an addition to the French claim of £300 million
on all heads, bringing it to £800 million in all.
The statements of M. Dubois and M. Loucheur were made in the
early spring of 1919. A speech delivered by M. Klotz before the
French Chamber six months later (5 September 1919), was less
excusable. In this speech the French Minister of Finance
estimated the total French claims for damage to property
(presumably inclusive of losses at sea, etc., but apart from
pensions and allowances) at £5,360 million (134 milliard francs),
or more than six times my estimate. Even if my figure prove
erroneous, M. Klotz's can never have been justified. So grave has
been the deception practised on the French people by their
ministers that when the inevitable enlightenment comes, as it
soon must (both as to their own claims and as to Germany's
capacity to meet them), the repercussions will strike at more
than M. Klotz, and may even involve the order of government and
society for which he stands.
British claims on the present basis would be practically
limited to losses by sea-losses of hulls and losses of cargoes.
Claims would lie, of course, for damage to civilian property in
air raids and by bombardment from the sea, but in relation to
such figures as we are now dealing with, the money value involved
is insignificant -- £5 million might cover them all, and £10
million would certainly do so.
The British mercantile vessels lost by enemy action,
excluding fishing vessels, numbered 2,479, with an aggregate of
7,759,090 tons gross.(16*) There is room for considerable
divergence of opinion as to the proper rate to take for
replacement cost; at the figure of £30 per gross ton, which with
the rapid growth of shipbuilding may soon be too high but can be
replaced by any other which better authorities(17*) may prefer,
the aggregate claim is £230 million. To this must be added the
loss of cargoes, the value of which is almost entirely a matter
of guesswork. An estimate of £40 per ton of shipping lost may be
as good an approximation as is possible, that is to say £310
million, making £540 million altogether.
An addition to this of £30 million, to cover air raids,
bombardments, claims of interned civilians, and miscellaneous
items of every description, should be more than sufficient --
making a total claim for Great Britain of £570 million. It is
surprising, perhaps, that the money value of our claim should be
so little short of that of France and actually in excess of that
of Belgium. But, measured either by pecuniary loss or real loss
to the economic power of the country, the injury to our
mercantile marine was enormous.
There remain the claims of Italy, Serbia, and Roumania for
damage by invasion and of these and other countries, as for
example Greece,(18*) for losses at sea. I will assume for the
present argument that these claims rank against Germany, even
when they were directly caused not by her but by her allies; but
that it is not proposed to enter any such claims on behalf of
Russia.(19*) Italy's losses by invasion and at sea cannot be very
heavy, and a figure of from £50 million to £100 million would be
fully adequate to cover them. The losses of Serbia, although from
a human point of view her sufferings were the greatest of
all,(20*) are not measured pecuniarily by very great figures, on
account of her low economic development. Dr Stamp (loc. cit.)
quotes an estimate by the Italian statistician Maroi, which puts
the national wealth of Serbia at £480 million or £105 per
head,(21*) and the greater part of this would be represented by
land which has sustained no permanent damage.(22*) In view of the
very inadequate data for guessing at more than the general
magnitude of the legitimate claims of this group of countries, I
prefer to make one guess rather than several and to put the
figure for the whole group at the round sum of £250 million.
We are finally left with the following --
Million £
Belgium 500(23*)
France 800
Great Britain 570
Other Allies 250
Total 2,120
I need not impress on the reader that there is much guesswork
in the above, and the figure for France in particular is likely
to be criticised. But I feel some confidence that the general
magnitude, as distinct from the precise figures, is not
hopelessly erroneous; and this may be expressed by the statement
that a claim against Germany, based on the interpretation of the
pre-armistice engagements of the Allied Powers which is adopted
above, would assuredly be found to exceed £1,600 million and to
fall short of £3,000 million.
This is the amount of the claim which we were entitled to
present to the enemy. For reasons which will appear more fully
later on, I believe that it would have been a wise and just act
to have asked the German government at the peace negotiations to
agree to a sum of £2,000 million in final settlement without
further examination of particulars. This would have provided an
immediate and certain solution, and would have required from
Germany a sum which, if she were granted certain indulgences, it
might not have proved entirely impossible for her to pay. This
sum should have been divided up amongst the Allies themselves on
a basis of need and general equity.
But the question was not settled on its merits.
II. THE CONFERENCE AND THE TERMS OF THE TREATY
I do not believe that, at the date of the armistice,
responsible authorities in the Allied countries expected any
indemnity from Germany beyond the cost of reparation for the
direct material damage which had resulted from the invasion of
Allied territory and from the submarine campaign. At that time
there were serious doubts as to whether Germany intended to
accept our terms, which in other respects were inevitably very
severe, and it would have been thought an unstatesmanlike act to
risk a continuance of the war by demanding a money payment which
Allied opinion was not then anticipating and which probably could
not be secured in any case. The French, I think, never quite
accepted this point of view; but it was certainly the British
attitude; and in this atmosphere the pre-armistice conditions
were framed.
A month later the atmosphere had changed completely. We had
discovered how hopeless the German position really was, a
discovery which some, though not all, had anticipated, but which
no one had dared reckon on as a certainty. It was evident that we
could have secured unconditional surrender if we had determined
to get it.
But there was another new factor in the situation which was
of greater local importance. The British Prime Minister had
perceived that the conclusion of hostilities might soon bring
with it the break-up of the political bloc upon which he was
depending for his personal ascendancy, and that the domestic
difficulties which would be attendant on demobilisation, the
turnover of industry from war to peace conditions, the financial
situation, and the general psychological reactions of men's
minds, would provide his enemies with powerful weapons, if he
were to leave them time to mature. The best chance, therefore, of
consolidating his power, which was personal and exercised, as
such, independently of party or principle to an extent unusual in
British politics, evidently lay in active hostilities before the
prestige of victory had abated, and in an attempt to found on the
emotions of the moment a new basis of power which might outlast
the inevitable reactions of the near future. Within a brief
period, therefore, after the armistice, the popular victor, at
the height of his influence and his authority, decreed a general
election. It was widely recognised at the time as an act of
political immorality. There were no grounds of public interest
which did not call for a short delay until the issues of the new
age had a little defined themselves, and until the country had
something more specific before it on which to declare its mind
and to instruct its new representatives. But the claims of
private ambition determined otherwise.
For a time all went well. But before the campaign was far
advanced government candidates were finding themselves
handicapped by the lack of an effective cry. The War Cabinet was
demanding a further lease of authority on the ground of having
won the war. But partly because the new issues had not yet
defined themselves, partly out of regard for the delicate balance
of a Coalition party, the Prime Minister's future policy was the
subject of silence or generalities. The campaign seemed,
therefore, to fall a little flat. In the light of subsequent
events it seems improbable that the Coalition party was ever in
real danger. But party managers are easily 'rattled'. The Prime
Minister's more neurotic advisers told him that he was not safe
from dangerous surprises, and the Prime Minister lent an ear to
them. The party managers demanded more 'ginger'. The Prime
Minister looked about for some.
On the assumption that the return of the Prime Minister to
power was the primary consideration, the rest followed naturally.
At that juncture there was a clamour from certain quarters that
the government had given by no means sufficiently clear
undertakings that they were not going 'to let the Hun off'. Mr
Hughes was evoking a good deal of attention by his demands for a
very large indemnity(24*) and Lord Northcliffe was lending his
powerful aid to the same cause. This pointed the Prime Minister
to a stone for two birds. By himself adopting the policy of Mr
Hughes and Lord Northcliffe, he could at the same time silence
those powerful critics and provide his party managers with an
effective platform cry to drown the increasing voices of
criticism from other quarters.
The progress of the General Election of 1918 affords a sad,
dramatic history of the essential weakness of one who draws his
chief inspiration not from his own true impulses, but from the
grosser effluxions of the atmosphere which momentarily surrounds
him. The Prime Minister's natural instincts, as they so often
are, were right and reasonable. He himself did not believe in
hanging the Kaiser or in the wisdom or the possibility of a great
indemnity. On the 22nd of November he and Mr Bonar Law issued
their election manifesto. It contains no allusion of any kind
either to the one or to the other, but, speaking, rather, of
disarmament and the League of Nations, concludes that 'our first
task must be to conclude a just and lasting peace, and so to
establish the foundations of a new Europe that occasion for
further wars may be for ever averted'. In his speech at
Wolverhampton on the eve of the dissolution (24 November), there
is no word of reparation or indemnity. On the following day at
Glasgow, Mr Bonar Law would promise nothing. 'We are going to the
conference,, he said, 'as one of a number of allies, and you
cannot expect a member of the government, whatever he may think,
to state in public before he goes into that conference, what line
he is going to take in regard to any particular question.' But a
few days later at Newcastle (29 November) the Prime Minister was
warming to his work: 'When Germany defeated France she made
France pay. That is the principle which she herself has
established. There is absolutely no doubt about the principle,
and that is the principle we should proceed upon -- that Germany
must pay the costs of the war up to the limit of her capacity to
do so.' But he accompanied this statement of principle with many
' words of warning, as to the practical difficulties of the case:
'We have appointed a strong committee of experts, representing
every shade of opinion, to consider this question very carefully
and to advise us. There is no doubt as to the justice of the
demand. She ought to pay, she must pay as far as she can, but we
are not going to allow her to pay in such a way as to wreck our
industries.' At this stage the Prime Minister sought to indicate
that he intended great severity, without raising excessive hopes
of actually getting the money, or committing himself to a
particular line of action at the conference. It was rumoured that
a high City authority had committed himself to the opinion that
Germany could certainly pay £20,000 million and that this
authority for his part would not care to discredit a figure of
twice that sum. The Treasury officials, as Mr Lloyd George
indicated, took a different view. He could, therefore, shelter
himself behind the wide discrepancy between the opinions of his
different advisers, and regard the precise figure of Germany's
capacity to pay as an open question in the treatment of which he
must do his best for his country's interests. As to our
engagements under the Fourteen Points he was always silent.
On 30 November, Mr Barnes, a member of the War Cabinet, in
which he was supposed to represent Labour, shouted from a
platform, 'I am for hanging the Kaiser.'
On 6 December, the Prime Minister issued a statement of
policy and aims in which he stated, with significant emphasis on
the word European, that 'All the European Allies have accepted
the principle that the Central Powers must pay the cost of the
war up to the limit of their capacity.'
But it was now little more than a week to polling day, and
still he had not said enough to satisfy the appetites of the
moment. On 8 December The Times, providing as usual a cloak of
ostensible decorum for the lesser restraint of its associates,
declared in a leader entitled 'Making Germany pay,' that 'the
public mind was still bewildered by the Prime Minister's various
statements.' 'There is too much suspicion', they added, 'of
influences concerned to let the Germans off lightly 'whereas the
only possible motive in determining their capacity to pay must be
the interests of the Allies.' 'It is the candidate who deals with
the issues of today,' wrote their political correspondent, 'who
adopts Mr Barnes's phrase about "hanging the Kaiser" and plumps
for the payment of the cost of the war by Germany, who rouses his
audience and strikes the notes to which they are most
responsive.'
On 9 December, at the Queen's Hall, the Prime Minister
avoided the subject. But from now on, the debauchery of thought
and speech progressed hour by hour. The grossest spectacle was
provided by Sir Eric Geddes in the Guildhall at Cambridge. An
earlier speech in which, in a moment of injudicious candour, he
had cast doubts on the possibility of extracting from Germany the
whole cost of the war had been the object of serious suspicion,
and he had therefore a reputation to regain. 'We will get out of
her all you can squeeze out of a lemon and a bit more,' the
penitent shouted, 'I will squeeze her until you can hear the
pips, squeak'; his policy was to take every bit of property
belonging to Germans in neutral and Allied countries, and all her
gold and silver and her jewels, and the contents of her
picture-galleries and libraries, to sell the proceeds for the
Allies' benefit. 'I would strip Germany,' he cried, 'as she has
stripped Belgium.'
By 11 December the Prime Minister had capitulated. His final
manifesto of six points issued on that day to the electorate
furnishes a melancholy comparison with his programme of three
weeks earlier. I quote it in full:
- Trial of the Kaiser.
- Punishment of those responsible for atrocities.
- Fullest indemnities from Germany.
- Britain for the British, socially and
industrially.
- rehabilitation of those broken in the war.
- A happier country for all.
Here is food for the cynic. To this concoction of greed and
sentiment, prejudice and deception, three weeks of the platform
had reduced the powerful governors of England, who but a little
while before had spoken not ignobly of disarmament and a League
of Nations and of a just and lasting peace which should establish
the foundations of a new Europe.
On the same evening the Prime Minister at Bristol withdrew in
effect his previous reservations and laid down four principles to
govern his indemnity policy, of which the chief were: First, we
have an absolute right to demand the whole cost of the war;
second, we propose to demand the whole cost of the war; and
third, a committee appointed by direction of the Cabinet believe
that it can be done.(25*) Four days later he went to the polls.
The Prime Minister never said that he himself believed that
Germany could pay the whole cost of the war. But the programme
became in the mouths of his supporters on the hustings a great
deal more concrete. The ordinary voter was led to believe that
Germany could certainly be made to pay the greater part, if not
the whole cost of the war. Those whose practical and selfish
fears for the future the expenses of the war had aroused, and
those whose emotions its horrors had disordered, were both
provided for. A vote for a Coalition candidate meant the
crucifixion of Antichrist and the assumption by Germany of the
British national debt.
It proved an irresistible combination, and once more Mr
George's political instinct was not at fault. No candidate could
safely denounce this programme, and none did so. The old Liberal
party, having nothing comparable to offer to the electorate, was
swept out of existence.(26*) A new House of Commons came into
being, a majority of whose members had pledged themselves to a
great deal more than the Prime Minister's guarded promises.
Shortly after their arrival at Westminster I asked a Conservative
friend, who had known previous Houses, what he thought of them.
'They are a lot of hard-faced men', he said, 'who look as if they
had done very well out of the war.'
This was the atmosphere in which the Prime Minister left for
Paris, and these the entanglements he had made for himself. He
had pledged himself and his government to make demands of a
helpless enemy inconsistent with solemn engagements on our part,
on the faith of which this enemy had laid down his arms. There
are few episodes in history which posterity will have less reason
to condone -- a war ostensibly waged in defence of the sanctity
of international engagements ending a definite breach of one of
the most sacred possible of such engagements on the part of the
victorious champions of these ideals.(27*)
Apart from other aspects of the transaction, I believe that
the campaign for securing out of Germany the general costs of the
war was one of the most serious acts of political unwisdom for
which our statesmen have ever been responsible. To what a
different future Europe might have looked forward if either Mr
Lloyd George or Mr Wilson had apprehended that the most serious
of the problems which claimed their attention were not political
or territorial but financial and economic, and that the perils of
the future lay not in frontiers or sovereignties but in food,
coal, and transport. Neither of them paid adequate attention to
these problems at any stage of the conference. But in any event
the atmosphere for the wise and reasonable consideration of them
was hopelessly befogged by the commitments of the British
delegation on the question of indemnities. The hopes to which the
Prime Minister had given rise not only compelled him to advocate
an unjust and unworkable economic basis to the treaty with
Germany, but set him at variance with the President, and on the
other hand with competing interests to those of France and
Belgium. The clearer it became that but little could be expected
from Germany, the more necessary it was to exercise patriotic
greed and 'sacred egotism' and snatch the bone from the juster
claims and greater need of France or the well-founded
expectations of Belgium. Yet the financial problems which were
about to exercise Europe could not be solved by greed. The
possibility of their cure lay in magnanimity.
Europe, if she is to survive her troubles, will need so much
magnanimity from America, that she must herself practise it. It
is useless for the Allies, hot from stripping Germany and one
another, to turn for help to the United States to put the states
of Europe, including Germany, on to their feet again. If the
General Election of December 1918 had been fought on lines of
prudent generosity instead of imbecile greed, how much better the
financial prospect of Europe might now be. I still believe that
before the main conference, or very early in its proceedings, the
representatives of Great Britain should have entered deeply, with
those of the United States, into the economic and financial
situation as a whole, and that the former should have been
authorised to make concrete proposals on the general lines (1)
that all inter-Allied indebtedness be cancelled outright; (2)
that the sum to be paid by Germany be fixed at £2,000 million;
(3) that Great Britain renounce all claim to participation in
this sum, and that any share to which she proves entitled be
placed at the disposal of the conference for the purpose of
aiding the finances of the new states about to be established;
(4) that in order to make some basis of credit immediately
available an appropriate proportion of the German obligations
representing the sum to be paid by her should be guaranteed by
all parties to the treaty; and (5) that the ex-enemy Powers
should also be allowed, with a view to their economic
restoration, to issue a moderate amount of bonds carrying a
similar guarantee. Such proposals involved an appeal to the
generosity of the United States. But that was inevitable; and, in
view of her far less financial sacrifices, it was an appeal which
could fairly have been made to her. Such proposals would have
been practicable. There is nothing in them quixotic or Utopian.
And they would have opened up for Europe some prospect of
financial stability and reconstruction.
The further elaboration of these ideas, however, must be left
to chapter 7, and we must return to Paris. I have described the
entanglements which Mr Lloyd George took with him. The position
of the finance ministers of the other Allies was even worse. We
in Great Britain had not based our financial arrangements on any
expectation of an indemnity. Receipts from such a source would
have been more or less in the nature of a windfall; and, in spite
of subsequent developments, there was an expectation at that time
of balancing our budget by normal methods. But this was not the
case with France or Italy. Their peace budgets made no pretence
of balancing, and had no prospects of doing so, without some
far-reaching revision of the existing policy. Indeed, the
position was and remains nearly hopeless. These countries were
heading for national bankruptcy. This fact could only be
concealed by holding out the expectation of vast receipts from
the enemy. As soon as it was admitted that it was in fact
impossible to make Germany pay the expenses of both sides, and
that the unloading of their liabilities upon the enemy was not
practicable, the position of the Ministers of Finance of France
and Italy became untenable.
Thus a scientific consideration of Germany's capacity to pay
was from the outset out of court. The expectations which the
exigencies of politics had made it necessary to raise were so
very remote from the truth that a slight distortion of figures
was no use, and it was necessary to ignore the facts entirely.
The resulting unveracity was fundamental. On a basis of so much
falsehood it became impossible to erect any constructive
financial policy which was workable. For this reason amongst
others, a magnanimous financial policy was essential. The
financial position of France and Italy was so bad that it was
impossible to make them listen to reason on the subject of the
German indemnity, unless one could at the same time point out to
them some alternative mode of escape from their troubles.(28*)
The representatives of the United States were greatly at fault,
in my judgment, for having no constructive proposals whatever to
offer to a suffering and distracted Europe.
It is worth while to point out in passing a further element
in the situation, namely, the opposition which existed between
the 'crushing' policy of M. Clemenceau and the financial
necessities of M. Klotz. Clemenceau's aim was to weaken and
destroy Germany in every possible way, and I fancy that he was
always a little contemptuous about the indemnity; he had no
intention of leaving Germany in a position to practise a vast
commercial activity. But he did not trouble his head to
understand either the indemnity or poor M. Klotz's overwhelming
financial difficulties. If it amused the financiers to put into
the treaty some very large demands, well there was no harm in
that; but the satisfaction of these demands must not be allowed
to interfere with the essential requirements of a Carthaginian
peace. The combination of the 'real' policy of M. Clemenceau on
unreal issues, with M. Klotz's policy of pretence on what were
very real issues indeed, introduced into the treaty a whole set
of incompatible provisions, over and above the inherent
impracticabilities of the reparation proposals.
I cannot here describe the endless controversy and intrigue
between the Allies themselves, which at last after some months
culminated in the presentation to Germany of the reparation
chapter in its final form. There can have been few negotiations
in history so contorted, so miserable, so utterly unsatisfactory
to all parties. I doubt if anyone who took much part in that
debate can look back on it without shame. I must be content with
an analysis of the elements of the final compromise which is
known to all the world.
The main point to be settled was, of course, that of the
items for which Germany could fairly be asked to make payment. Mr
Lloyd George's election pledge to the effect that the Allies were
entitled to demand from Germany the entire costs of the war was
from the outset clearly untenable; or rather, to put it more
impartially, it was clear that to persuade the President of the
conformity of this demand with our pre-armistice engagements was
beyond the powers of the most plausible. The actual compromise
finally reached is to be read as follows in the paragraphs of the
treaty as it has been published to the world.
Article 231 reads: 'The Allied and Associated governments
affirm and Germany accepts the responsibility of Germany and her
allies for causing all the loss and damage to which the Allied
and Associated governments and their nationals have been
subjected as a consequence of the war imposed upon them by the
aggression of Germany and her allies.' This is a well and
carefully drafted article; for the President could read it as
statement of admission on Germany's part of moral responsibility
for bringing about the war, while the Prime Minister could
explain it as an admission of financial liability for the general
costs of the war. Article 232 continues: 'The Allied and
Associated governments recognise that the resources of Germany
are not adequate, after taking into account permanent diminutions
of such resources which will result from other provisions of the
present treaty, to make complete reparation for all such loss and
damage.' The President could comfort himself that this was no
more than a statement of undoubted fact, and that to recognise
that Germany cannot pay a certain claim does not imply that she
is liable to pay the claim; but the Prime Minister could point
out that in the context it emphasises to the reader the
assumption of Germany's theoretic liability asserted in the
preceding article. Article 232 proceeds: 'The Allied and
Associated governments, however, require, and Germany undertakes,
that she will make compensation for all damage done to the
civilian population of the Allied and Associated Powers and to
their property during the period of the belligerency of each as
an Allied or Associated Power against Germany by such aggression
by land, by sea, and from the air, and in general all damage as
defined in annex I hereto.'(29*) The words italicised, being
practically a quotation from the pre-armistice conditions,
satisfied the scruples of the President, while the additions of
the words 'and in general all damage as defined in annex I
hereto' gave the Prime Minister a chance in annex I.
So far, however, all this is only a matter of words, of
virtuosity in draftsmanship, which does no one any harm, and
which probably seemed much more important at the time than it
ever will again between now and judgment day. For substance we
must turn to annex I.
A great part of annex I is in strict conformity with the pre-
armistice conditions or, at any rate, does not strain them beyond
what is fairly arguable. Paragraph 1 claims damage done for
injury to the persons of civilians or, in the case of death, to
their dependants, as a direct consequence of acts of war;
paragraph 2, for acts of cruelty, violence, or maltreatment on
the part of the enemy towards civilian victims; paragraph 3, for
enemy acts injurious to health or capacity to work or to honour
towards civilians in occupied or invaded territory; paragraph 8,
for forced labour exacted by the enemy from civilians; paragraph
9, for damage done to property 'with the exception of naval and
military works or materials' as a direct consequence of
hostilities; and paragraph 10, for fines and levies imposed by
the enemy upon the civilian population. All these demands are
just and in conformity with the Allies' rights.
Paragraph 4, which claims for 'damage caused by any kind of
maltreatment of prisoners of war', is more doubtful on the strict
letter, but may be justifiable under the Hague convention and
involves a very small sum.
In paragraphs 5, 6, and 7, however, an issue of immensely
greater significance is involved. These paragraphs assert a claim
for the amount of the separation and similar allowances granted
during the war by the Allied governments to the families of
mobilised persons, and for the amount of the pensions and
compensations in respect of the injury or death of combatants
payable by these governments now and hereafter. Financially this
adds to the bill, as we shall see below, a very large amount,
indeed about twice as much again as all the other claims added
together.
The reader will readily apprehend what a plausible case can
be made out for the inclusion of these items of damage, if only
on sentimental grounds. It can be pointed out, first of all, that
from the point of view of general fairness it is monstrous that a
woman whose house is destroyed should be entitled to claim from
the enemy whilst a woman whose husband is killed on the field of
battle should not be so entitled; or that a farmer deprived of
his farm should claim but that a woman deprived of the earning
power of her husband should not claim. In fact the case for
including pensions and separation allowances largely depends on
exploiting the rather arbitrary character of the criterion laid
down in the pre-armistice conditions. Of all the losses caused by
war some bear more heavily on individuals and some are more
evenly distributed over the community as a whole; but by means of
compensations granted by the government many of the former are in
fact converted into the latter. The most logical criterion for a
limited claim, falling short of the entire costs of the war,
would have been in respect of enemy acts contrary to
international engagements or the recognised practices of warfare.
But this also would have been very difficult to apply and unduly
unfavourable to French interests as compared with Belgium (whose
neutrality Germany had guaranteed) and Great Britain (the chief
sufferer from illicit acts of submarines).
In any case the appeals to sentiment and fairness outlined
above are hollow; for it makes no difference to the recipient of
a separation allowance or a pension whether the state which pays
them receives compensation on this or on another head, and a
recovery by the state out of indemnity receipts is just as much
in relief of the general taxpayer as a contribution towards the
general costs of the war would have been. But the main
consideration is that it was too late to consider whether the
pre-armistice conditions were perfectly judicious and logical or
to amend them; the only question at issue was whether these
conditions were not in fact limited to such classes of direct
damage to civilians and their property as are set forth in
paragraphs 1, 2, 3, 8, 9, and 10 of annex I. If words have any
meaning, or engagements any force, we had no more right to claim
for those war expenses of the state which arose out of pensions
and separation allowances, than for any other of the general
costs of the war. And who is prepared to argue in detail that we
were entitled to demand the latter?
What had really happened was a compromise between the Prime
Minister's pledge to the British electorate to claim the entire
costs of the war and the pledge to the contrary which the Allies
had given to Germany at the armistice. The Prime Minister could
claim that although he had not secured the entire costs of the
war, he had nevertheless secured an important contribution
towards them, that he had always qualified his promises by the
limiting condition of Germany's capacity to pay, and that the
bill as now presented more than exhausted this capacity as
estimated by the more sober authorities. The President, on the
other hand, had secured a formula which was not too obvious a
breach of faith, and had avoided a quarrel with his associates on
an issue where the appeals to sentiment and passion would all
have been against him, in the event of its being made a matter of
open popular controversy. In view of the Prime Minister's
election pledges, the President could hardly hope to get him to
abandon them in their entirety without a struggle in public; and
the cry of pensions would have had an overwhelming popular appeal
in all countries. Once more the Prime Minister had shown himself
a political tactician of a high order.
A further point of great difficulty may be readily perceived
between the lines of the treaty. It fixes no definite sum as
representing Germany's liability. This feature has been the
subject of very general criticism -- that it is equally
inconvenient to Germany and to the Allies themselves that she
should not know what she has to pay or they what they are to
receive. The method, apparently contemplated by the treaty, of
arriving at the final result over a period of many months by an
addition of hundreds of thousands of individual claims for damage
to land, farm buildings, and chickens, is evidently
impracticable; and the reasonable course would have been for both
parties to compound for a round sum without examination of
details. If this round sum had been named in the treaty, the
settlement would have been placed on a more business-like basis.
But this was impossible for two reasons. Two different kinds
of false statement had been widely promulgated, one as to
Germany's capacity to pay, the other as to the amount of the
Allies' just claims in respect of the devastated areas. The
fixing of either of these figures presented a dilemma. A figure
for Germany's prospective capacity to pay, not too much in excess
of the estimates of most candid and well-informed authorities,
would have fallen hopelessly far short of popular expectations
both in England and in France. On the other hand, a definitive
figure for damage done which would not disastrously disappoint
the expectations which had been raised in France and Belgium
might have been incapable of substantiation under challenge,(30*)
and open to damaging criticism on the part of the Germans, who
were believed to have been prudent enough to accumulate
considerable evidence as to the extent of their own misdoings.
By far the safest course for the politicians was, therefore,
to mention no figure at all; and from this necessity a great deal
of the complication of the reparation chapter essentially
springs.
The reader may be interested, however, to have my estimate of
the claim which can in fact be substantiated under annex I of the
reparation chapter. In the first section of this chapter I have
already guessed the claims other than those for pensions and
separation allowances at £3,000 million (to take the extreme
upper limit of my estimate). The claim for pensions and
separation allowances under annex I is not to be based on the
actual cost of these compensations to the governments concerned,
but is to be a computed figure calculated on the basis of the
scales in force in France at the date of the treaty's coming into
operation. This method avoids the invidious course of valuing an
American or a British life at a higher figure than a French or an
Italian. The French rate for pensions and allowances is at an
intermediate rate, not so high as the American or British, but
above the Italian, the Belgian, or the Serbian. The only data
required for the calculation are the actual French rates, and the
numbers of men mobilised and of the casualties in each class of
the various Allied armies. None of these figures are available in
detail, but enough is known of the general level of allowances,
of the numbers involved, and of the casualties suffered to allow
of an estimate which may not be very wide of the mark. My guess
as to the amount to be added in respect of pensions and
allowances is as follows:
Million £
British Empire 1,400
France 2,400(31*)
Italy 500
Others
(including United States) 700
Total 5,000
I feel much more confidence in the approximate accuracy of
the total figure(32*) than in its division between the different
claimants. The reader will observe that in any case the addition
of pensions and allowances enormously increases the aggregate
claim, raising it indeed by nearly double. Adding this figure to
the estimate under other heads, we have a total claim against
Germany of £8,000 million.(33*) I believe that this figure is
fully high enough, and that the actual result may fall somewhat
short of it.(34*) In the next section of this chapter the
relation of this figure to Germany's capacity to pay will be
examined. It is only necessary here to remind the reader of
certain other particulars of the treaty which speak for
themselves:
- Out of the total amount of the claim, whatever it
eventually turns out to be, a sum of £1,000 million must be paid
before 1 May 1921. The possibility of this will be discussed
below. But the treaty itself provides certain abatements. In the
first place, this sum is to include the expenses of the armies of
occupation since the armistice (a large charge of the order of
magnitude of £200 million which under another article of the
treaty -- no. 249 -- is laid upon Germany).(35*) But further,
'such supplies of food and raw materials as may be judged by the
governments of the Principal Allied and Associated Powers to be
essential to enable Germany to meet her obligations for
reparation may also, with the approval of the said governments,
be paid for out of the above sum.'(36*) This is a qualification
of high importance. The clause, as it is drafted, allows the
finance ministers of the Allied countries to hold out to their
electorates the hope of substantial payments at an early date,
while at the same time it gives to the reparation commission a
discretion, which the force of facts will compel them to
exercise, to give back to Germany what is required for the
maintenance of her economic existence. This discretionary power
renders the demand for an immediate payment of £1,000 million
less injurious than it would otherwise be, but nevertheless it
does not render it innocuous. In the first place, my conclusions
in the next section of this chapter indicate that this sum cannot
be found within the period indicated, even if a large proportion
is in practice returned to Germany for the purpose of enabling
her to pay for imports. In the second place, the reparation
commission can only exercise its discretionary power effectively
by taking charge of the entire foreign trade of Germany, together
with the foreign exchange arising out of it, which will be quite
beyond the capacity of any such body. If the reparation
commission makes any serious attempt to administer the collection
of this sum of £1,000 million, and to authorise the return to
Germany of a part of it, the trade of Central Europe will be
strangled by bureaucratic regulation in its most inefficient
form.
- In addition to the early payment in cash or kind of a sum
of £1,000 million, Germany is required to deliver bearer bonds to
a further amount of £2,000 million or, in the event of the
payments in cash or kind before 1 May 1921, available for
reparation, falling short of £1,000 million by reason of the
permitted deductions, to such further amount as shall bring the
total payments by Germany in cash, kind, and bearer bonds up to 1
May 1921, to a figure of £3,000 million altogether.(37*) These
bearer bonds carry interest at 2 1/2% per annum from 1921 to
1925, and at 5% plus 1% for amortisation thereafter. Assuming,
therefore, that Germany is not able to provide any appreciable
surplus towards reparation before 1921, she will have to find a
sum of £75 million annually from 1921 to 1925, and £180 million
annually thereafter.(38*)
- As soon as the reparation commission is satisfied that
Germany can do better than this, 5% bearer bonds are to be issued
for a further £2,000 million, the rate of amortisation being
determined by the commission hereafter. This would bring the
annual payment to £280 million without allowing anything for the
discharge of the capital of the last £2,000 million.
- Germany's liability, however, is not limited to £5,000
million, and the reparation commission is to demand further
instalments of bearer bonds until the total enemy liability under
annex I has been provided for. On the basis of my estimate of
£8,000 million for the total liability, which is more likely to
be criticised as being too low than as being too high, the amount
of this balance will be £3,000 million. Assuming interest at 5%,
this will raise the annual payment to £430 million. without
allowance for amortisation.
- But even this is not all. There is a further provision of
devastating significance. Bonds representing payments in excess
of £3,000 million are not to be issued until the commission is
satisfied that Germany can meet the interest on them. But this
does not mean that interest is remitted in the meantime. As from
1 May 1921, interest is to be debited to Germany on such part of
her outstanding debt as has not been covered by payment in cash
or kind or by the issue of bonds as above,(39*) and 'the rate of
interest shall be 5 per cent unless the commission shall
determine at some future time that circumstances justify a
variation of this rate.' That is to say, the capital sum of
indebtedness is rolling up all the time at compound interest. The
effect of this provision towards increasing the burden is, on the
assumption that Germany cannot pay very large sums at first,
enormous. At 5% compound interest a capital sum doubles itself in
fifteen years. On the assumption that Germany cannot pay more
than £150 million annually until 1936 (i.e. 5% interest on £3,000
million) the £5,000 million on which interest is deferred will
have risen to £10,000 million, carrying an annual interest charge
of £500 million. That is to say, even if Germany pays £150
million annually up to 1936, she will nevertheless owe us at that
date more than half as much again as she does now (£13,000
million as compared with £8,000 million). From 1936 onwards she
will have to pay to us £650 million annually in order to keep
pace with the interest alone. At the end of any year in which she
pays less than this sum she will owe more than she did at the
beginning of it. And if she is to discharge the capital sum in
thirty years from 1936, i.e. in forty-eight years from the
armistice, she must pay an additional £130 million annually,
making £780 million in all.(40*)
It is, in my judgment, as certain as anything can be, for
reasons which I will elaborate in a moment, that Germany cannot
pay anything approaching this sum. Until the treaty is altered,
therefore, Germany has in effect engaged herself to hand over to
the Allies the whole of her surplus production in perpetuity.
- This is not less the case because the reparation
commission has been given discretionary powers to vary the rate
of interest, and to postpone and even to cancel the capital
indebtedness. In the first place, some of these powers can only
be exercised if the commission or the governments represented on
it are unanimous.(41*) But also, which is perhaps more important,
it will be the duty of the reparation commission, until there has
been a unanimous and far-reaching change of the policy which the
treaty represents, to extract from Germany year after year the
maximum sum obtainable. There is a great difference between
fixing a definite sum, which though large is within Germany's
capacity to pay and yet to retain a little for herself, and
fixing a sum far beyond her capacity, which is then to be reduced
at the discretion of a foreign commission acting with the object
of obtaining each year the maximum which the circumstances of
that year permit. The first still leaves her with some slight
incentive for enterprise, energy, and hope. The latter skins her
alive year by year in perpetuity, and however skilfully and
discreetly the operation is performed, with whatever regard for
not killing the patient in the process, it would represent a
policy which, if it were really entertained and deliberately
practised, the judgment of men would soon pronounce to be one of
the most outrageous acts of a cruel victor in civilised history.
There are other functions and powers of high significance
which the treaty accords to the reparation commission. But these
will be most conveniently dealt with in a separate section.
III. GERMANY'S CAPACITY TO PAY
The forms in which Germany can discharge the sum which she
has engaged herself to pay are three in number --
(1) immediately transferable wealth in the form of gold,
ships, and foreign securities; (2) the value of property in ceded
territory, or surrendered under the armistice; (3) annual
payments spread over a term of years, partly in cash and partly
in materials such as coal products, potash, and dyes.
There is excluded from the above the actual restitution of
property removed from territory occupied by the enemy, as, for
example, Russian gold, Belgian and French securities, cattle,
machinery, and works of art. In so far as the actual goods taken
can be identified and restored, they must clearly be returned to
their rightful owners, and cannot be brought into the general
reparation pool. This is expressly provided for in article 238 of
the treaty.
- Immediately transferable wealth
- Gold. After deduction of the gold to be returned to
Russia, the official holding of gold as shown in the Reichsbank's
return of 30 November 1918 amounted to £115,417,900. This was a
very much larger amount than had appeared in the Reichsbank's
return prior to the war,(42*) and was the result of the vigorous
campaign carried on in Germany during the war for the surrender
to the Reichsbank not only of gold coin but of gold ornaments of
every kind. Private hoards doubtless still exist but, in view of
the great efforts already made, it is unlikely that either the
German government or the Allies will be able to unearth them. The
return can therefore be taken as probably representing the
maximum amount which the German government are able to extract
from their people. In addition to gold there was in the
Reichsbank a sum of about £1 million in silver. There must be,
however, a further substantial amount in circulation, for the
holdings of the Reichsbank were as high as £9.1 million on 31
December 1917, and stood at about £6 million up to the latter
part of October 1918, when the internal run began on currency of
every kind.(43*) We may, therefore, take a total of (say) £125
million for gold and silver together at the date of the
armistice.
These reserves, however, are no longer intact. During the
long period which elapsed between the armistice and the peace it
became necessary for the Allies to facilitate the provisioning of
Germany from abroad. The political condition of Germany at that
time and the serious menace of Spartacism rendered this step
necessary in the interests of the Allies themselves if they
desired the continuance in Germany of a stable government to
treat with. The question of how such provisions were to be paid
for presented, however, the gravest difficulties. A series of
conferences was held at Trèves, at Spa, at Brussels, and
subsequently at Château Villette and Versailles, between
representatives of the Allies and of Germany, with the object of
finding some method of payment as little injurious as possible to
the future prospects of reparation payments. The German
representatives maintained from the outset that the financial
exhaustion of their country was for the time being so complete
that a temporary loan from the Allies was the only possible
expedient. This the Allies could hardly admit at a time when they
were preparing demands for the immediate payment by Germany of
immeasurably larger sums. But, apart from this, the German claim
could not be accepted as strictly accurate so long as their gold
was still untapped and their remaining foreign securities
unmarketed. In any case, it was out of the question to suppose
that in the spring of 1919 public opinion in the Allied countries
or in America would have allowed the grant of a substantial loan
to Germany. On the other hand, the Allies were naturally
reluctant to exhaust on the provisioning of Germany the gold
which seemed to afford one of the few obvious and certain sources
for reparation. Much time was expended in the exploration of all
possible alternatives. but it was evident at last that, even if
German exports and saleable foreign securities had been available
to a sufficient value, they could not be liquidated in time, and
that the financial exhaustion of Germany was so complete that
nothing whatever was immediately available in substantial amounts
except the gold in the Reichsbank. Accordingly a sum exceeding
£50 million in all out of the Reichsbank gold was transferred by
Germany to the Allies (chiefly to the United States, Great
Britain, however, also receiving a substantial sum) during the
first six months of 1919 in payment for foodstuffs.
But this was not all. Although Germany agreed, under the
first extension of the armistice, not to export gold without
Allied permission, this permission could not be always withheld.
There were liabilities of the Reichsbank accruing in the
neighbouring neutral countries, which could not be met otherwise
than in gold. The failure of the Reichsbank to meet its
liabilities would have caused a depreciation of the exchange so
injurious to Germany's credit as to react on the future prospects
of reparation. In some cases, therefore, permission to export
gold was accorded to the Reichsbank by the Supreme Economic
Council of the Allies.
The net result of these various measures was to reduce the
gold reserve of the Reichsbank by more than half, the figures
falling from £115 million to £55 million in September 1919.
It would be possible under the treaty to take the whole of
this latter sum for reparation purposes. It amounts, however, as
it is, to less than 4 % of the Reichsbank's note issue, and the
psychological effect of its total confiscation might be expected
(having regard to the very large volume of mark-notes held
abroad) to destroy the exchange value of the mark almost
entirely. A sum of £5 million, £10 million, or even £20 million
might be taken for a special purpose. But we may assume that the
reparation commission will judge it imprudent, having regard to
the reaction on their future prospects of securing payment, to
ruin the German currency system altogether, more particularly
because the French and Belgian governments, being holders of a
very large volume of mark-notes formerly circulating in the
occupied or ceded territory have a great interest in maintaining
some exchange value for the mark, quite apart from reparation
prospects.
It follows, therefore, that no sum worth speaking of can be
expected in the form of gold or silver towards the initial
payment of £1,000 million due by 1921.
- Shipping. Germany has engaged, as we have seen above, to
surrender to the Allies virtually the whole of her merchant
shipping. A considerable part of it, indeed, was already in the
hands of the Allies prior to the conclusion of peace, either by
detention in their ports or by the provisional transfer of
tonnage under the Brussels agreement in connection with the
supply of foodstuffs.(44*) Estimating the tonnage of German
shipping to be taken over under the treaty at 4 million gross
tons, and the average value per ton at £30 per ton, the total
money value involved is £120 million.(45*)
- Foreign securities. Prior to the census of foreign
securities carried out by the German government in September
1916,(46*) of which the exact results have not been made public,
no official return of such investments was ever called for in
Germany, and the various unofficial estimates are confessedly
based on insufficient data, such as the admission of foreign
securities to the German stock exchanges, the receipts of the
stamp duties, consular reports, etc. The principal German
estimates current before the war are given in the appended
footnote.(47*) This shows a general consensus of opinion among
German authorities that their net foreign investments were
upwards of £1,250 million. I take this figure as the basis of my
calculations, although I believe it to be an exaggeration; £1,000
million would probably be a safer figure.
Deductions from this aggregate total have to be made under
four heads.
- Investments in Allied countries and in the United States,
which between them constitute a considerable part of the world,
have been sequestrated by Public Trustees, custodians of enemy
property, and similar officials, and are not available for
reparation except in so far as they show a surplus over various
private claims. Under the scheme for dealing with enemy debts
outlined in chapter 4, the first charge on these assets is the
private claims of Allied against German nationals. It is
unlikely, except in the United States, that there will be any
appreciable surplus for any other purpose.
- Germany's most important fields of foreign investment
before the war were not, like ours, overseas, but in Russia,
Austria-Hungary, Turkey, Roumania, and Bulgaria. A great part of
these has now become almost valueless, at any rate for the time
being; especially those in Russia and Austria-Hungary. If present
market value is to be taken as the test, none of these
investments are now saleable above a nominal figure. Unless the
Allies are prepared to take over these securities much above
their nominal market valuation, and hold them for future
realisation, there is no substantial source of funds for
immediate payment in the form of investments in these countries.
- While Germany was not in a position to realise her
foreign investments during the war to the degree that we were,
she did so nevertheless in the case of certain countries and to
the extent that she was able. Before the United States came into
the war, she is believed to have resold a large part of the pick
of her investments in American securities, although some current
estimates of these sales (a figure of £60 million has been
mentioned) are probably exaggerated. But throughout the war and
particularly in its later stages, when her exchanges were weak
and her credit in the neighbouring neutral countries was becoming
very low, she was disposing of such securities as Holland,
Switzerland, and Scandinavia would buy or would accept as
collateral. It is reasonably certain that by June 1919 her
investments in these countries had been reduced to a negligible
figure and were far exceeded by her liabilities in them. Germany
has also sold certain overseas securities, such as Argentine
cedulas, for which a market could be found.
- It is certain that since the armistice there has been a
great flight abroad of the foreign securities still remaining in
private hands. This is exceedingly difficult to prevent. German
foreign investments are as a rule in the form of bearer
securities and are not registered. They are easily smuggled
abroad across Germany's extensive land frontiers, and for some
months before the conclusion of peace it was certain that their
owners would not be allowed to retain them if the Allied
governments could discover any method of getting hold of them.
These factors combined to stimulate human ingenuity, and the
efforts both of the Allied and of the German governments to
interfere effectively with the outflow are believed to have been
largely futile.
In face of all these considerations, it will be a miracle if
much remains for reparation. The countries of the Allies and of
the United States, the countries of Germany's own allies, and the
neutral countries adjacent to Germany exhaust between them almost
the whole of the civilised world; and, as we have seen, we cannot
expect much to be available for reparation from investments in
any of these quarters. Indeed there remain no countries of
importance for investments except those of South America.
To convert the significance of these deductions into figures
involves much guesswork. I give the reader the best personal
estimate I can form after pondering the matter in the light of
the available figures and other relevant data.
I put the deduction under (i) at £300 million, of which £100
million may be ultimately available after meeting private debts,
etc.
As regards (ii) -- according to a census taken by the
Austrian Ministry of Finance on 31 December 1912, the nominal
value of the Austro-Hungarian securities held by Germans was
£197,300,000. Germany's pre-war investments in Russia outside
government securities have been estimated at £95 million, which
is much lower than would be expected, and in 1906 Sartorius von
Waltershausen estimated her investments in Russian government
securities at £150 million. This gives a total of £245 million,
which is to some extent borne out by the figure of £200 million
given in 1911 by Dr Ischchanian as a deliberately modest
estimate. A Roumanian estimate, published at the time of that
country's entry into the war, gave the value of Germany's
investments in Roumania at £4,000,000-£4,400,000, of which
£2,800,000-£3,200,000 were in government securities. An
association for the defence of French interests in Turkey, as
reported in the Temps (8 September 1919), has estimated the total
amount of German capital invested in Turkey at about £59 million,
of which, according to the latest Report of the council of
foreign bondholders, £32,500,000 was held by German nationals in
the Turkish external debt. No estimates are available to me of
Germany's investments in Bulgaria. Altogether I venture a
deduction of £500 million in respect of this group of countries
as a whole.
Resales and the pledging as collateral of securities during
the war under (iii) I put at £100 million to £150 million,
comprising practically all Germany's holding of Scandinavian,
Dutch, and Swiss securities, a part of her South American
securities, and a substantial proportion of her North American
securities sold prior to the entry of the United States into the
war.
As to the proper deduction under (iv) there are naturally no
available figures. For months past the European Press has been
full of sensational stories of the expedients adopted. But if we
put the value of securities which have already left Germany or
have been safely secreted within Germany itself beyond discovery
by the most inquisitorial and powerful methods at £100 million,
we are not likely to overstate it.
These various items lead, therefore, in all to a deduction of
a round figure of about £1,000 million, and leave us with an
amount of £250 million theoretically still available.(48*)
To some readers this figure may seem low, but let them
remember that it purports to represent the remnant of saleable
securities upon which the German government might be able to lay
hands for public purposes. In my own opinion it is much too high,
and considering the problem by a different method of attack I
arrive at a lower figure. For leaving out of account sequestered
Allied securities and investments in Austria, Russia, etc., what
blocks of securities, specified by countries and enterprises, can
Germany possibly still have which could amount to as much as £250
million? I cannot answer the question. She has some Chinese
government securities which have not been sequestered, a few
Japanese perhaps, and a more substantial value of first-class
South American properties. But there are very few enterprises of
this class still in German hands, and even their value is
measured by one or two tens of millions, not by fifties or
hundreds. He would be a rash man, in my judgment, who joined a
syndicate to pay £100 million in cash for the unsequestered
remnant of Germany's overseas investments. If the reparation
commission is to realise even this lower figure, it is probable
that they will have to nurse, for some years, the assets which
they take over, not attempting their disposal at the present
time.
We have, therefore, a figure of from £100 million to £250
million as the maximum contribution from Germany's foreign
securities.
Her immediately transferable wealth is composed, then, of:
(a) gold and silver -- say £60 million; (b) ships -- £120
million; (c) foreign securities -- £100–250 million.
Of the gold and silver, it is not, in fact, practicable to
take any substantial part without consequences to the German
currency system injurious to the interests of the Allies
themselves. The contribution from all these sources together
which the reparation commission can hope to secure by May 1921
may be put, therefore, at from £250 million to £350 million as a
maximum.(49*)
- Property in ceded territory or surrendered under the armistace
As the treaty has been drafted Germany will not receive
important credits available towards meeting reparation in respect
of her property in ceded territory.
Private property in most of the ceded territory is utilised
towards discharging private German debts to Allied nationals, and
only the surplus, if any, is available towards reparation. The
value of such property in Poland and the other new states is
payable direct to the owners.
Government property in Alsace-Lorraine, in territory ceded to
Belgium, and in Germany's former colonies transferred to a
mandatory, is to be forfeited without credit given. Buildings,
forests, and other state property which belonged to the former
kingdom of Poland are also to be surrendered without credit.
There remain, therefore, government properties, other than the
above, surrendered to Poland, government properties in Schleswig
surrendered to Denmark,(50*) the value of the Saar coalfields,
the value of certain river craft, etc., to be surrendered under
the ports, waterways, and railways chapter, and the value of the
German submarine cables transferred under annex VII of the
reparation chapter.
Whatever the treaty may say, the reparation commission will
not secure any cash payments from Poland. I believe that the Saar
coalfields have been valued at from £15 million to £20 million. A
round figure of £30 million for all the above items, excluding
any surplus available in respect of private property, is probably
a liberal estimate.
There remains the value of material surrendered under the
armistice. Article 250 provides that a credit shall be assessed
by the reparation commission for rolling-stock surrendered under
the armistice as well as for certain other specified items, and
generally for any material so surrendered for which the
reparation commission think that credit should be given, 'as
having non-military value'. The rolling-stock (150,000 wagons and
5,000 locomotives) is the only very valuable item. A round figure
of £50 million, for all the armistice surrenders, is probably
again a liberal estimate.
We have, therefore, £80 million to add in respect of this
heading to our figure of £250-350 million under the previous
heading. This figure differs from the preceding in that it does
not represent cash capable of benefiting the financial situation
of the Allies, but is only a book credit between themselves or
between them and Germany.
The total of £330 million to £430 million now reached is not,
however, available for reparation. The first charge upon it,
under article 251 of the treaty, is the cost of the armies of
occupation both during the armistice and after the conclusion of
peace. The aggregate of this figure up to May 1921 cannot be
calculated until the rate of withdrawal is known which is to
reduce the monthly cost from the figure exceeding £20 million
which prevailed during the first part of 1919, to that of £1
million, which is to be the normal figure eventually. I estimate,
however, that this aggregate may be about £200 million. This
leaves us with from £100 million to £200 million still in hand.
Out of this, and out of exports of goods, and payments in
kind under the treaty prior to May 1921 (for which I have not as
yet made any allowance), the Allies have held out the hope that
they will allow Germany to receive back such sums for the
purchase of necessary food and raw materials as the former deem
it essential for her to have. It is not possible at the present
time to form an accurate judgment either as to the money-value of
the goods which Germany will require to purchase from abroad in
order to re-establish her economic life, or as to the degree of
liberality with which the Allies will exercise their discretion.
If her stocks of raw materials and food were to be restored to
anything approaching their normal level by May 1921, Germany
would probably require foreign purchasing power of from £100 to
£200 million at least, in addition to the value of her current
exports. While this is not likely to be permitted, I venture to
assert as a matter beyond reasonable dispute that the social and
economic condition of Germany cannot possibly permit a surplus of
exports over imports during the period prior to May 1921, and
that the value of any payments in kind with which she may be able
to furnish the Allies under the treaty in the form of coal, dyes,
timber, or other materials will have to be returned to her to
enable her to pay for imports essential to her existence.(51*)
The reparation commission can, therefore, expect no addition
from other sources to the sum of from £100 million to £200
million with which we have hypothetically credited it after the
realisation of Germany's immediately transferable wealth, the
calculation of the credits due to Germany under the treaty, and
the discharge of the cost of the armies of occupation. As Belgium
has secured a private agreement with France, the United States,
and Great Britain, outside the treaty, by which she is to
receive, towards satisfaction of her claims, the first £100
million available for reparation, the upshot of the whole matter
is that Belgium may possibly get her £100 million by May 1921,
but none of the other Allies are likely to secure by that date
any contribution worth speaking of. At any rate, it would be very
imprudent for finance ministers to lay their plans on any other
hypothesis.
- Annual payments spread over a term of years
It is evident that Germany's pre-war capacity to pay an
annual foreign tribute has not been unaffected by the almost
total loss of her colonies, her overseas connections, her
mercantile marine, and her foreign properties, by the cession of
ten per cent of her territory and population, of one-third of her
coal and of three-quarters of her iron ore, by two million
casualties amongst men in the prime of life, by the starvation of
her people for four years, by the burden of a vast war debt, by
the depreciation of her currency to less than one-seventh its
former value, by the disruption of her allies and their
territories, by revolution at home and Bolshevism on her borders,
and by all the unmeasured ruin in strength and hope of four years
of all-swallowing war and final defeat.
All this, one would have supposed, is evident. Yet most
estimates of a great indemnity from Germany depend on the
assumption that she is in a position to conduct in the future a
vastly greater trade than ever she has had in the past.
For the purpose of arriving at a figure it is of no great
consequence whether payment takes the form of cash (or rather of
foreign exchange) or is partly effected in kind (coal, dyes,
timber, etc.), as contemplated by the treaty. In any event, it is
only by the export of specific commodities that Germany can pay,
and the method of turning the value of these exports to account
for reparation purposes is, comparatively, a matter of detail.
We shall lose ourselves in mere hypothesis unless we return
in some degree to first principles and, whenever we can, to such
statistics as there are. It is certain that an annual payment can
only be made by Germany over a series of years by diminishing her
imports and increasing her exports, thus enlarging the balance in
her favour which is available for effecting payments abroad.
Germany can pay in the long run in goods, and in goods only,
whether these goods are furnished direct to the Allies, or
whether they are sold to neutrals and the neutral credits so
arising are then made over to the Allies. The most solid basis
for estimating the extent to which this 'process can be carried
is to be found, therefore, in an analysis of her trade returns
before the war. Only on the basis of such an analysis,
supplemented by some general data as to the aggregate
wealth-producing capacity of the country, can a rational guess be
made as to the maximum degree to which the exports of Germany
could be brought to exceed her imports.
In the year 1913 Germany's imports amounted to £538 million
and her exports to £505 million, exclusive of transit trade and
bullion. That is to say, imports exceeded exports by about £33
million. On the average of the five years ending 1913, however,
her imports exceeded her exports by a substantially larger
amount, namely, £74 million. It follows, therefore, that more
than the whole of Germany's pre-war balance for new foreign
investment was derived from the interest on her existing foreign
securities, and from the profits of her shipping, foreign
banking, etc. As her foreign properties and her mercantile marine
are now to be taken from her, and as her foreign banking and
other miscellaneous sources of revenue from abroad have been
largely destroyed, it appears that, on the pre-war basis of
exports and imports, Germany, so far from having a surplus
wherewith to make a foreign payment, would be not nearly
self-supporting. Her first task, therefore, must be to effect a
readjustment of consumption and production to cover this deficit.
Any further economy she can effect in the use of imported
commodities, and any further stimulation of exports will then be
available for reparation.
Two-thirds of Germany's import and export trade is enumerated
under separate headings in the following tables. The
considerations applying to the enumerated portions may be assumed
to apply more or less to the remaining one-third, which is
composed of commodities of minor importance individually.
German exports, 1913 Amount Percentage of
(million £) total exports
Iron goods (including
tin-plates, etc.) 66.13 13.2
Machinery and parts
(including motor-cars) 37.55 7.5
Coal, coke, and briquettes 35.34 7.0
Woollen goods (including
raw and combined wool
and clothing) 29.40 5.9
Cotton goods (including
raw cotton, yarn and thread) 28.15 5.6
196.57 39.2
Cereals, etc. (including
rye, oats, wheat, hops) 21.18 4.1
Leather and leather goods 15.47 3.0
Sugar 13.20 2.6
Paper, etc. 13.10 2.6
Furs 11.75 2.2
Electrical goods
(installations, machinery,
lamps, cables) 10.88 2.2
Silk goods 10.10 2.0
Dyes 9.76 1.9
Copper goods 6.50 1.3
Toys 5.15 1.0
Rubber and rubber goods 4.27 0.9
Books, maps, and music 3.71 0.8
Potash 3.18 0.6
Glass 3.14 0.6
Potassium chloride 2.91 0.6
Pianos, organs, and parts 2.77 0.6
Raw zinc 2.74 0.5
Porcelain 2.53 0.5
142.34 28.0
Other goods, unenumerated 165.92 32.8
Total 504.83 100.0
German imports, 1913 Amount Percentage of
(million £) total imports
1. Raw materials:
Cotton 30.35 5.6
Hides and skins 24.86 4.6
Wool 23.67 4.4
Copper 16.75 3.1
Coal 13.66 2.5
Timber 11.60 2.2
Iron ore 11.35 2.1
Furs 9.35 1.7
Flax and flaxseed 9.33 1.7
Saltpetre 8.55 1.6
Silk 7.90 1.5
Rubber 7.30 1.4
Jute 4.70 0.9
Petroleum 3.49 0.7
Tin 2.91 0.5
Phosphorus chalk 2.32 0.4
Lubricating oil 2.29 0.4
190.38 35.3
II. Food, tobacco, etc.:
Cereals, etc. (wheat,
barley, bran, rice, maize,
oats, rye, clover) 65.51 12.2
Oilseeds and cake, etc.
(including palm kernels,
copra, cocoa beans) 20.53 3.8
Cattle, lamb fat, bladders 14.62 2.8
Coffee 10.95 2.0
Eggs 9.70 1.8
Tobacco 6.70 1.2
Butter 5.93 1.1
Horses 5.81 1.1
Fruit 3.65 0.7
Fish 2.99 0.6
Poultry 2.80 0.5
Wine 2.67 0.5
151.86 28.3
III. Manufactures:
Cotton yarn and thread
and cotton goods 9.41 1.8
Woollen yarn and
woollen goods 7.57 1.4
Machinery 4.02 0.7
21.00 3.9
IV. Unenumerated 175.28 32.5
Total 538.52 100.0
These tables show that the most important exports consisted
of: (1) iron goods, including tin-plates (13.2%); (2) machinery,
etc. (7.5%); (3) coal, coke, and briquettes (7%); (4) woollen
goods, including raw and combed wool (5.9 %); and (5) cotton
goods, including cotton yarn and thread and raw cotton (5.6%),
these five classes between them accounting for 39.2% of the total
exports. It will be observed that all these goods are of a kind
in which before the war competition between Germany and the
United Kingdom was very severe. If, therefore, the volume of such
exports to overseas or European destinations is very largely
increased the effect upon British export trade must be
correspondingly serious. As regards two of the categories,
namely, cotton and woollen goods, the increase of an export trade
is dependent upon an increase of the import of the raw material,
since Germany produces no cotton and practically no wool. These
trades are therefore incapable of expansion unless Germany is
given facilities for securing these raw materials (which can only
be at the expense of the Allies) in excess of the pre-war
standard of consumption, and even then the effective increase is
not the gross value of the exports, but only the difference
between the value of the manufactured exports and of the imported
raw material. As regards the other three categories, namely,
machinery, iron goods, and coal, Germany's capacity to increase
her exports will have been taken from her by the cessions of
territory in Poland, Upper Silesia, and Alsace-Lorraine. As has
been pointed out already, these districts accounted for nearly
one-third of Germany's production of coal. But they also supplied
no less than three-quarters of her iron-ore production, 38% of
her blast furnaces, and 9.5% of her iron and steel foundries.
Unless, therefore, Alsace-Lorraine and Upper Silesia send their
iron ore to Germany proper, to be worked up, which will involve
an increase in the imports for which she will have to find
payment, so far from any increase in export trade being possible,
a decrease is inevitable.(52*)
Next on the list come cereals, leather goods, sugar, paper,
furs, electrical goods, silk goods, and dyes. Cereals are not a
net export and are far more than balanced by imports of the same
commodities. As regards sugar, nearly 90 per cent of Germany's
pre-war exports came to the United Kingdom.(53*) An increase in
this trade might be stimulated by the grant of a preference in
this country to German sugar or by an arrangement by which sugar
was taken in part payment for the indemnity on the same lines as
has been proposed for coal, dyes, etc. Paper exports also might
be capable of some increase. Leather goods, furs, and silks
depend upon corresponding imports on the other side of the
account. Silk goods are largely in competition with the trade of
France and Italy. The remaining items are individually very
small. I have heard it suggested that the indemnity might be paid
to a great extent in potash and the like. But potash before the
war represented 0.6% of Germany's export trade, and about £3
million in aggregate value. Besides, France, having secured a
potash field in the territory which has been restored to her,
will not welcome a great stimulation of the German exports of
this material.
An examination of the import list shows that 63.6% are raw
materials and food. The chief items of the former class, namely,
cotton, wool, copper, hides, iron ore, furs, silk, rubber, and
tin, could not be much reduced without reacting on the export
trade, and might have to be increased if the export trade was to
be increased. Imports of food, namely, wheat, barley, coffee,
eggs, rice, maize, and the like, present a different problem. It
is unlikely that, apart from certain comforts, the consumption of
food by the German labouring classes before the war was in excess
of what was required for maximum efficiency; indeed, it probably
fell short of that amount. Any substantial decrease in the
imports of food would therefore react on the efficiency of the
industrial population, and consequently on the volume of surplus
exports which they could be forced to produce. It is hardly
possible to insist on a greatly increased productivity of German
industry if the workmen are to be underfed. But this may not be
equally true of barley, coffee, eggs, and tobacco. If it were
possible to enforce a régime in which for the future no German
drank beer or coffee, or smoked any tobacco, a substantial saving
could be effected. Otherwise there seems little room for any
significant reduction.
The following analysis of German exports and imports
according to destination and origin is also relevant. From this
it appears that of Germany's exports in 1913, 18% went to the
British empire, 17% to France, Italy, and Belgium, 10% to Russia
and Roumania, and 7% to the United States; that is to say, more
than half of the exports found their market in the countries of
the Entente nations. Of the balance, 12% went to Austria-Hungary,
Turkey, and Bulgaria, and 35% elsewhere. Unless, therefore, the
present Allies are prepared to encourage the importation of
German products, a substantial increase in total volume can only
be effected by the wholesale swamping of neutral markets.
GERMAN TRADE (1913) ACCORDING TO DESTINATION AND ORIGIN
Destination of Germany's Origin of Germany's
exports imports
Million £ Per cent Million £ Per cent
Great Britain 71.91 14.2 43.80 8.1
India 7.53 1.5 27.04 5.0
Egypt 2.17 0.4 5.92 1.1
Canada 3.02 0.6 3.20 0.6
Australia 4.42 0.9 14.80 2.8
South Africa 2.34 0.5 3.48 0.6
Total,
British empire 91.39 18.1 98.24 18.2
France 39.49 7.8 29.21 5.4
Belgium 27.55 5.5 17.23 3.2
Italy 19.67 3.9 15.88 3.0
U.S.A. 35.66 7.1 85.56 15.9
Russia 44.00 8.7 71.23 13.2
Roumania 7.00 1.4 3.99 0.7
Austria-Hungary 55.24 10.9 41.36 7.7
Turkey 4.92 1.0 3.68 0.7
Bulgaria 1.51 0.3 0.40 ---
Other counties 178.04 35.3 171.74 32.0
504.47 100.0 538.52 100.0
The above analysis affords some indication of the possible
magnitude of the maximum modification of Germany's export balance
under the conditions which will prevail after the peace. On the
assumptions (1) that we do not specially favour Germany over
ourselves in supplies of such raw materials as cotton and wool
(the world's supply of which is limited), (2) that France, having
secured the iron-ore deposits, makes a serious attempt to secure
the blast furnaces and the steel trade also, (3) that Germany is
not encouraged and assisted to undercut the iron and other trades
of the Allies in overseas markets, and (4) that a substantial
preference is not given to German goods in the British empire, it
is evident by examination of the specific items that not much is
practicable.
Let us run over the chief items again: (1) Iron goods. In
view of Germany's loss of resources, an increased net export
seems impossible and a large decrease probable. (2) Machinery.
Some increase is possible. (3) Coal and coke. The value of
Germany's net export before the war was £22 million; the Allies
have agreed that for the time being 20 million tons is the
maximum possible export with a problematic (and in fact)
impossible increase to 40 million tons at some future time; even
on the basis of 20 million tons we have virtually no increase of
value, measured in pre-war prices;(54*) whilst, if this amount is
exacted, there must be a decrease of far greater value in the
export of manufactured articles requiring coal for their
production. (4) Woollen goods. An increase is impossible without
the raw wool, and, having regard to the other claims on supplies
of raw wool, a decrease is likely. (5) Cotton goods. The same
considerations apply as to wool. (6) Cereals. There never was and
never can be a net export. (7) Leather goods. The same
considerations apply as to wool.
We have now covered nearly half of Germany's pre-war exports,
and there is no other commodity which formerly represented as
much as 3 per cent of her exports. In what commodity is she to
pay? Dyes? -- their total value in 1913 was £10 million. Toys?
Potash? -- 1913 exports were worth £3 million. And even if the
commodities could be specified, in what markets are they to be
sold? -- remembering that we have in mind goods to the value not
of tens of millions annually, but of hundreds of millions.
On the side of imports, rather more is possible. By lowering
the standard of life, an appreciable reduction of expenditure on
imported commodities may be possible. But, as we have already
seen, many large items are incapable of reduction without
reacting on the volume of exports.
Let us put our guess as high as we can without being foolish,
and suppose that after a time Germany will be able, in spite of
the reduction of her resources, her facilities, her markets, and
her productive power, to increase her exports and diminish her
imports so as to improve her trade balance altogether by £100
million annually, measured in pre-war prices. This adjustment is
first required to liquidate the adverse trade balance, which in
the five years before the war averaged £74 million; but we will
assume that after allowing for this, she is left with a
favourable trade balance of £50 million a year. Doubling this to
allow for the rise in pre-war prices, we have a figure of £100
million. Having regard to the political, social, and human
factors, as well as to the purely economic, I doubt if Germany
could be made to pay this sum annually over a period of 30 years;
but it would not be foolish to assert or to hope that she could.
Such a figure, allowing 5% for interest, and 1% for repayment
of capital, represents a capital sum having a present value of
about £1,700 million.(55*)
I reach, therefore, the final conclusion that, including all
methods of payment -- immediately transferable wealth, ceded
property, and an annual tribute -- £2,000 million is a safe
maximum figure of Germany's capacity to pay. In all the actual
circumstances, I do not believe that she can pay as much. Let
those who consider this a very low figure, bear in mind the
following remarkable comparison. The wealth of France in 1871 was
estimated at a little less than half that of Germany in 1913.
Apart from changes in the value of money, an indemnity from
Germany of £500 million would, therefore, be about comparable to
the sum paid by France in 1871; and as the real burden of an
indemnity increases more than in proportion to its amount, the
payment of £2,000 million by Germany would have far severer
consequences than the £200 million paid by France in 1871.
There is only one head under which I see a possibility of
adding to the figure reached on the line of argument adopted
above; that is, if German labour is actually transported to the
devastated areas and there engaged in the work of reconstruction.
I have heard that a limited scheme of this kind is actually in
view. The additional contribution thus obtainable depends on the
number of labourers which the German government could contrive to
maintain in this way and also on the number which, over a period
of years, the Belgian and French inhabitants would tolerate in
their midst. In any case, it would seem very difficult to employ
on the actual work of reconstruction, even over a number of
years, imported labour having a net present value exceeding (say)
£250 million; and even this would not prove in practice a net
addition to the annual contributions obtainable in other ways.
A capacity of £8,000 million or even of £5,000 million is,
therefore, not within the limits of reasonable possibility. It is
for those who believe that Germany can make an annual payment
amounting to hundreds of millions sterling to say in what
specific commodities they intend this payment to be made, and in
what markets the goods are to be sold. Until they proceed to some
degree of detail, and are able to produce some tangible argument
in favour of their conclusions, they do not deserve to be
believed.(56*)
I make three provisos only, none of which affect the force of
my argument for immediate practical purposes.
First: if the Allies were to 'nurse' the trade and industry
of Germany for a period of five or ten years, supplying her with
large loans, and with ample shipping, food, and raw materials
during that period, building up markets for her, and deliberately
applying all their resources and goodwill to making her the
greatest industrial nation in Europe, if not in the world, a
substantially larger sum could probably be extracted thereafter;
for Germany is capable of very great productivity.
Second: whilst I estimate in terms of money, I assume that
there is no revolutionary change in the purchasing power of our
unit of value. If the value of gold were to sink to a half or a
tenth of its present value, the real burden of a payment fixed in
terms of gold would be reduced proportionately. If a gold
sovereign comes to be worth what a shilling is worth now, then,
of course, Germany can pay a larger sum than I have named,
measured in gold sovereigns.
Third: I assume that there is no revolutionary change in the
yield of nature and material to man's labour. It is not
impossible that the progress of science should bring within our
reach methods and devices by which the whole standard of life
would be raised immeasurably, and a given volume of products
would represent but a portion of the human effort which it
represents now. In this case all standards of 'capacity' would be
changed everywhere. But the fact that all things are possible is
no excuse for talking foolishly.
It is true that in 1870 no man could have predicted Germany's
capacity in 1910. We cannot expect to legislate for a generation
or more. The secular changes in man's economic condition and the
liability of human forecast to error are as likely to lead to
mistake in one direction as in another. We cannot as reasonable
men do better than base our policy on the evidence we have and
adapt it to the five or ten years over which we may suppose
ourselves to have some measure of prevision; and we are not at
fault if we leave on one side the extreme chances of human
existence and of revolutionary changes in the order of Nature or
of man's relations to her. The fact that we have no adequate
knowledge of Germany's capacity to pay over a long period of
years is no justification (as I have heard some people claim that
it is) for the statement that she can pay ten thousand million
pounds.
Why has the world been so credulous of the unveracities of
politicians? If an explanation is needed, I attribute this
particular credulity to the following influences in part.
In the first place, the vast expenditures of the war, the
inflation of prices, and the depreciation of currency, leading up
to a complete instability of the unit of value, have made us lose
all sense of number and magnitude in matters of finance. What we
believed to be the limits of possibility have been so enormously
exceeded, and those who founded their expectations on the past
have been so often wrong, that the man in the street is now
prepared to believe anything which is told him with some show of
authority, and the larger the figure the more readily he swallows
it.
But those who look into the matter more deeply are sometimes
misled by a fallacy much more plausible to reasonable persons.
Such a one might base his conclusions on Germany's total surplus
of annual productivity as distinct from her export surplus.
Helfferich's estimate of Germany's annual increment of wealth in
1913 was £400 million to £425 million (exclusive of increased
money value of existing land and property). Before the war,
Germany spent between £50 million and £100 million on armaments,
with which she can now dispense. Why, therefore, should she not
pay over to the Allies an annual sum of £500 million? This puts
the crude argument in its strongest and most plausible form.
But there are two errors in it. First of all, Germany's
annual savings, after what she has suffered in the war and by the
peace, will fall far short of what they were before and, if they
are taken from her year by year in future, they cannot again
reach their previous level. The loss of Alsace-Lorraine, Poland,
and Upper Silesia could not be assessed in terms of surplus
productivity at less than £50 million annually. Germany is
supposed to have profited about £100 million per annum from her
ships, her foreign investments, and her foreign banking and
connections, all of which have now been taken from her. Her
saving on armaments is far more than balanced by her annual
charge for pensions, now estimated at £250 million,(57*) which
represents a real loss of productive capacity. And even if we put
on one side the burden of the internal debt, which amounts to 240
milliards of marks, as being a question of internal distribution
rather than of productivity, we must still allow for the foreign
debt incurred by Germany during the war, the exhaustion of her
stock of raw materials, the depletion of her livestock, the
impaired productivity of her soil from lack of manures and of
labour, and the diminution in her wealth from the failure to keep
up many repairs and renewals over a period of nearly five years.
Germany is not as rich as she was before the war, and the
diminution in her future savings for these reasons, quite apart
from the factors previously allowed for, could hardly be put at
less than ten per cent, that is £40 million annually.
These factors have already reduced Germany's annual surplus
to less than the £100 million at which we arrived on other
grounds as the maximum of her annual payments. But even if the
rejoinder be made that we have not yet allowed for the lowering
of the standard of life and comfort in Germany which may
reasonably be imposed on a defeated enemy,(58*) there is still a
fundamental fallacy in the method of calculation. An annual
surplus available for home investment can only be converted into
a surplus available for export abroad by a radical change in the
kind of work performed. Labour, while it may be available and
efficient for domestic services in Germany, may yet be able to
find no outlet in foreign trade. We are back on the same question
which faced us in our examination of the export trade -- in what
export trade is German labour going to find a greatly increased
outlet? Labour can only be diverted into new channels with loss
of efficiency, and a large expenditure of capital. The annual
surplus which German labour can produce for capital improvements
at home is no measure, either theoretically or practically, of
the annual tribute which she can pay abroad.
IV. THE REPARATION COMMISSION
This body is so remarkable a construction and may, if it
functions at all, exert so wide an influence on the life of
Europe, that its attributes deserve a separate examination.
There are no precedents for the indemnity imposed on Germany
under the present treaty; for the money exactions which formed
part of the settlement after previous wars have differed in two
fundamental respects from this one. The sum demanded has been
determinate and has been measured in a lump sum of money; and so
long as the defeated party was meeting the annual instalments of
cash, no further interference was necessary.
But for reasons already elucidated, the exactions in this
case are not yet determinate, and the sum when fixed will prove
in excess of what can be paid in cash and in excess also of what
can be paid at all. It was necessary, therefore, to set up a body
to establish the bill of claim, to fix the mode of payment, and
to approve necessary abatements and delays. It was only possible
to place this body in a position to exact the utmost year by year
by giving it wide powers over the internal, economic life of the
enemy countries who are to be treated henceforward as bankrupt
estates to be administered by and for the benefit of the
creditors. In fact, however, its powers and functions have been
enlarged even beyond what was required for this purpose, and the
reparation commission has been established as the final arbiter
on numerous economic and financial issues which it was convenient
to leave unsettled in the treaty itself.(59*)
The powers and constitution of the reparation commission are
mainly laid down in articles 233-41 and annex II of the
reparation chapter of the treaty with Germany. But the same
commission is to exercise authority over Austria and Bulgaria,
and possibly over Hungary and Turkey, when peace is made with
these countries. There are therefore analogous articles mutatis
mutandis in the Austrian treaty(60*) and in the Bulgarian
treaty.(61*)
The principal Allies are each represented by one chief
delegate. The delegates of the United States, Great Britain,
France, and Italy take part in all proceedings; the delegate of
Belgium in all proceedings except those attended by the delegates
of Japan or the Serb-Croat-Slovene state; the delegate of Japan
in all proceedings affecting maritime or specifically Japanese
questions; and the delegate of the Serb-Croat-Slovene state when
questions relating to Austria, Hungary, or Bulgaria are under
consideration. Other Allies are to be represented by delegates,
without the power to vote, whenever their respective claims and
interests are under examination.
In general the commission decides by a majority vote, except
in certain specific cases where unanimity is required, of which
the most important are the cancellation of German indebtedness,
long postponement of the instalments, and the sale of German
bonds of indebtedness. The commission is endowed with full
executive authority to carry out its decisions. It may set up an
executive staff and delegate authority to its officers. The
commission and its staff are to enjoy diplomatic privileges, and
its salaries are to be paid by Germany, who will, however, have
no voice in fixing them. If the commission is to discharge
adequately its numerous functions, it will be necessary for it to
establish a vast polyglot bureaucratic organisation, with a staff
of hundreds. To this organisation, the headquarters of which will
be in Paris, the economic destiny of Central Europe is to be
entrusted.
Its main functions are as follows:
- The commission will determine the precise figure of the
claim against the enemy Powers by an examination in detail of the
claims of each of the Allies under annex I of the reparation
chapter. This task must be completed by May 1921. It shall give
to the German government and to Germany's allies 'a just
opportunity to be heard, but not to take any part whatever in the
decisions of the commission'. That is to say, the commission will
act as a party and a judge at the same time.
- Having determined the claim, it will draw up a schedule
of payments providing for the discharge of the whole sum with
interest within thirty years. From time to time it shall, with a
view to modifying the schedule within the limits of possibility,
'consider the resources and capacity of Germany... giving her
representatives a just opportunity to be heard'.
- 'In periodically estimating Germany's capacity to pay, the
commission shall examine the German system of taxation, first, to
the end that the sums for reparation which Germany is required to
pay shall become a charge upon all her revenues prior to that for
the service or discharge of any domestic loan, and secondly, so
as to satisfy itself that, in general, the German scheme of
taxation is fully as heavy proportionately as that of any of the
Powers represented on the commission.'
- Up to May 1921 the commission has power, with a view to
securing the payment of £1,000 million, to demand the surrender
of any piece of German property whatever, wherever situated: that
is to say, 'Germany shall pay in such instalments and in such
manner, whether in gold, commodities, ships, securities, or
otherwise, as the reparation commission may fix'.
- The commission will decide which of the rights and
interests of German nationals in public utility undertakings
operating in Russia, China, Turkey, Austria, Hungary, and
Bulgaria, or in any territory formerly belonging to Germany or
her allies, are to be expropriated and transferred to the
commission itself; it will assess the value of the interests so
transferred; and it will divide the spoils.
- The commission will determine how much of the resources
thus stripped from Germany must be returned to her to keep enough
life in her economic organisation to enable her to continue to
make reparation payments in future.(62*)
- The commission will assess the value, without appeal or
arbitration, of the property and rights ceded under the
Armistice, and under the Treaty -- rolling-stock, the mercantile
marine, river craft, cattle, the Saar mines, the property in
ceded territory for which credit is to be given, and so forth.
- The commission will determine the amounts and values
(within certain defined limits) of the contributions which
Germany is to make in kind year by year under the various annexes
to the reparation chapter.
- The commission will provide for the restitution by
Germany of property which can be identified.
- The commission will receive, administer, and distribute
all receipts from Germany in cash or in kind. It will also issue
and market German bonds of indebtedness.
- The commission will assign the share of the pre-war
public debt to be taken over by the ceded areas of Schleswig,
Poland, Danzig, and Upper Silesia. The commission will also
distribute the public debt of the late Austro-Hungarian empire
between its constituent parts.
- The Commission will liquidate the Austro-Hungarian Bank,
and will supervise the withdrawal and replacement of the currency
system of the late Austro-Hungarian empire.
- It is for the commission to report if, in their
judgment, Germany is falling short in fulfilment of her
obligations, and to advise methods of coercion.
- In general, the commission, acting through a subordinate
body, will perform the same functions for Austria and Bulgaria as
for Germany, and also, presumably, for Hungary and Turkey.(63*)
There are also many other relatively minor duties assigned to
the commission. The above summary, however, shows sufficiently
the scope and significance of its authority. This authority is
rendered of far greater significance by the fact that the demands
of the treaty generally exceed Germany's capacity. Consequently
the clauses which allow the commission to make abatements, if in
their judgment the economic conditions of Germany require it,
will render it in many different particulars the arbiter of
Germany's economic life. The commission is not only to inquire
into Germany's general capacity to pay, and to decide (in the
early years) what import of foodstuffs and raw materials is
necessary; it is authorised to exert pressure on the German
system of taxation (annex II, paragraph 12(b))(64*) and on German
internal expenditure, with a view to ensuring that reparation
payments are a first charge on the country's entire resources;
and it is to decide on the effect on German economic life of
demands for machinery, cattle, etc., and of the scheduled
deliveries of coal.
By article 240 of the treaty Germany expressly recognises the
commission and its powers 'as the same may be constituted by the
Allied and Associated governments', and 'agrees irrevocably to
the possession and exercise by such commission of the power and
authority given to it under the present treaty'. She undertakes
to furnish the commission with all relevant information. And
finally in article 241, 'Germany undertakes to pass, issue, and
maintain in force any legislation, orders, and decrees that may
be necessary to give complete effect to these provisions'.
The comments on this of the German financial commission at
Versailles were hardly an exaggeration: 'German democracy is thus
annihilated at the very moment when the German people was about
to build it up after a severe struggle -- annihilated by the very
persons who throughout the war never tired of maintaining that
they sought to bring democracy to us... Germany is no longer a
people and a state, but becomes a mere trade concern placed by
its creditors in the hands of a receiver, without its being
granted so much as the opportunity to prove its willingness to
meet its obligations of its own accord. The commission, which is
to have its permanent headquarters outside Germany, will possess
in Germany incomparably greater rights than the German emperor
ever possessed; the German people under its régime would remain
for decades to come shorn of all rights, and deprived, to a far
greater extent than any people in the days of absolutism, of any
independence of action, of any individual aspiration in its
economic or even in its ethical progress.'
In their reply to these observations the Allies refused to
admit that there was any substance, ground, or force in them.
'The observations of the German delegation', they pronounced,
'present a view of this commission so distorted and so inexact
that it is difficult to believe that the clauses of the treaty
have been calmly or carefully examined. It is not an engine of
oppression or a device for interfering with German sovereignty.
It has no forces at its command; it has no executive powers
within the territory of Germany; it cannot, as is suggested,
direct or control the educational or other systems of the
country. Its business is to ask what is to be paid; to satisfy
itself that Germany can pay; and to report to the Powers, whose
delegation it is, in case Germany makes default. If Germany
raises the money required in her own way, the commission cannot
order that it shall be raised in some other way. if Germany
offers payment in kind, the commission may accept such payment,
but, except as specified in the treaty itself, the commission
cannot require such a payment.'
This is not a candid statement of the scope and authority of
the reparation commission, as will be seen by a comparison of its
terms with the summary given above or with the treaty itself. Is
not, for example, the statement that the commission 'has no
forces at its command' a little difficult to justify in view of
article 430 of the treaty, which runs: 'In case, either during
the occupation or after the expiration of the fifteen years
referred to above, the reparation commission finds that Germany
refuses to observe the whole or part of her obligations under the
present treaty with regard to reparation, the whole or part of
the areas specified in article 429 will be reoccupied immediately
by the Allied and Associated Powers'? The decision as to whether
Germany has kept her engagements and whether it is possible for
her to keep them is left, it should be observed, not to the
League of Nations, but to the reparation commission itself; and
an adverse ruling on the part of the commission to is be followed
'immediately' by the use of armed force. Moreover, the
depreciation of the powers of the commission attempted in the
Allied reply largely proceeds from the assumption that it is
quite open to Germany to 'raise the money required in her own
way', in which case it is true that many of the powers of the
reparation commission would not come into practical effect;
whereas in truth one of the main reasons for setting up the
commission at all is the expectation that Germany will not be
able to carry the burden nominally laid upon her.
It is reported that the people of Vienna, hearing that a
section of the reparation commission is about to visit them, have
decided characteristically to pin their hopes on it. A financial
body can obviously take nothing from them, for they have nothing;
therefore this body must be for the purpose of assisting and
relieving them. Thus do the Viennese argue, still light-headed in
adversity. But perhaps they are right. The reparation commission
will come into very close contact with the problems of Europe;
and it will bear a responsibility proportionate to its powers. It
may thus come to fulfil a very different role from that which
some of its authors intended for it. Transferred to the League of
Nations, an organ of justice and no longer of interest, who knows
that by a change of heart and object the reparation commission
may not yet be transformed from an instrument of oppression and
rapine into an economic council of Europe, whose object is the
restoration of life and of happiness, even in the enemy
countries?
V. THE GERMAN COUNTER-PROPOSALS
The German counter-proposals were somewhat obscure, and also
rather disingenuous. It will be remembered that those clauses of
the reparation chapter which dealt with the issue of bonds by
Germany produced on the public mind the impression that the
indemnity had been fixed at £5,000 million, or at any rate at
this figure as a minimum. The German delegation set out,
therefore, to construct their reply on the basis of this figure,
assuming apparently that public opinion in Allied countries would
not be satisfied with less than the appearance of £5,000 million;
and, as they were not really prepared to offer so large a figure,
they exercised their ingenuity to produce a formula which might
be represented to Allied opinion as yielding this amount, whilst
really representing a much more modest sum. The formula produced
was transparent to anyone who read it carefully and knew the
facts, and it could hardly have been expected by its authors to
deceive the Allied negotiators. The German tactic assumed,
therefore, that the latter were secretly as anxious as the
Germans themselves to arrive at a settlement which bore some
relation to the facts, and that they would therefore be willing,
in view of the entanglements which they had got themselves into
with their own publics, to practise a little collusion in
drafting the treaty -- a supposition which in slightly different
circumstances might have had a good deal of foundation. As
matters actually were, this subtlety did not benefit them, and
they would have done much better with a straightforward and
candid estimate of what they believed to be the amount of their
liabilities on the one hand, and their capacity to pay on the
other.
The German offer of an alleged sum of £5,000 million amounted
to the following. In the first place it was conditional on
concessions in the treaty ensuring that 'Germany shall retain the
territorial integrity corresponding to the armistice
convention,(65*) that she shall keep her colonial possessions and
merchant ships, including those of large tonnage, that in her own
country and in the world at large she shall enjoy the same
freedom of action as all other peoples, that all war legislation
shall be at once annulled, and that all interferences during the
war with her economic rights and with German private property,
etc., shall be treated in accordance with the principle of
reciprocity'; that is to say, the offer is conditional on the
greater part of the rest of the treaty being abandoned. In the
second place, the claims are not to exceed a maximum of £5,000
million, of which £1,000 million is to be discharged by 1 May
1926; and no part of this sum is to carry interest pending the
payment of it.(66*) In the third place, there are to be allowed
as credits against it (amongst other things): (a) the value of
all deliveries under the armistice, including military material
(e.g. Germany's navy); (b) the value of all railways and state
property in ceded territory. (c) the pro rata, share of all ceded
territory in the Germany public debt (including the war debt) and
in the reparation payments which this territory would have had to
bear if it had remained part of Germany; and (d) the value of the
cession of Germany's claims for sums lent by her to her allies in
the war.(67*)
The credits to be deducted under (a), (b), (c), and (d) might
be in excess of those allowed in the actual treaty, according to
a rough estimate, by a sum of as much as £2,000 million, although
the sum to be allowed under (d) can hardly be calculated.
If, therefore, we are to estimate the real value of the
German offer of £5,000 million on the basis laid down by the
treaty, we must first of all deduct £2,000 million claimed for
offsets which the treaty does not allow, and then halve the
remainder in order to obtain the present value of a deferred
payment on which interest is not chargeable. This reduces the
offer to £1,500 million, as compared with the £8,000 million
which, according to my rough estimate, the treaty demands of her.
This in itself was a very substantial offer -- indeed it
evoked widespread criticism in Germany -- though, in view of the
fact that it was conditional on the abandonment of the greater
part of the rest of the treaty, it could hardly be regarded as a
serious one.(68*) But the German delegation might have done
better if they had stated in less equivocal language how far they
felt able to go.
In the final reply of the Allies to this counter-proposal
there is one important provision, which I have not attended to
hitherto, but which can be conveniently dealt with in this place.
Broadly speaking, no concessions were entertained on the
reparation chapter as it was originally drafted, but the Allies
recognised the inconvenience of the indeterminacy of the burden
laid upon Germany and proposed a method by which the final total
of claim might be established at an earlier date than 1 May 1921.
They promised, therefore, that at any time within four months of
the signature of the treaty (that is to say, up to the end of
October 1919), Germany should be at liberty to submit an offer of
a lump sum in settlement of her whole liability as defined in the
treaty, and within two months thereafter (that is to say, before
the end of 1919) the Allies 'will, so far as may be possible,
return their answers to any proposals that may be made.'
This offer is subject to three conditions. 'Firstly, the
German authorities will be expected, before making such
proposals, to confer with the representatives of the Powers
directly concerned. Secondly, such offers must be unambiguous and
must be precise and clear. Thirdly, they must accept the
categories and the reparation clauses as matters settled beyond
discussion.'
The offer, as made, does not appear to contemplate any
opening up of the problem of Germany's capacity to pay. It is
only concerned with the establishment of the total bill of claims
as defined in the treaty -- whether (e.g.) it is £7,000 million,
£8,000 million, or £10,000 million. 'The questions', the Allies'
reply adds, 'are bare questions of fact, namely, the amount of
the liabilities, and they are susceptible of being treated in
this way.'
If the promised negotiations are really conducted on these
lines, they are not likely to be fruitful. It will not be much
easier to arrive at an agreed figure before the end of 1919 than
it was at the time of the conference; and it will not help
Germany's financial position to know for certain that she is
liable for the huge sum which on any computation the treaty
liabilities must amount to. These negotiations do offer, however,
an opportunity of reopening the whole question of the reparation
payments, although it is hardly to be hoped that at so very early
a date, public opinion in the countries of the Allies has changed
its mood sufficiently.(69*)
I cannot leave this subject as though its just treatment
wholly depended either on our own pledges or on economic facts.
The policy of reducing Germany to servitude for a generation, of
degrading the lives of millions of human beings, and of depriving
a whole nation of happiness should be abhorrent and detestable --
abhorrent and detestable, even if it were possible, even if it
enriched ourselves, even if it did not sow the decay of the whole
civilised life of Europe. Some preach it in the name of justice.
In the great events of man's history, in the unwinding of the
complex fates of nations, justice is not so simple. And if it
were, nations are not authorised, by religion or by natural
morals, to visit on the children of their enemies the misdoings
of parents or of rulers.
NOTES:
- 'With reservation that any future claims and demands of the
Allies and the United States of America remain unaffected, the
following financial conditions are required: Reparation for
damage done. While armistice lasts, no public securities shall be
removed by the enemy which can serve as a pledge to the Allies
for recovery or reparation of war losses. Immediate restitution
of cash deposit in National Bank of Belgium, and, in general,
immediate return of all documents, of specie, stock, shares,
paper money, together with plant for issue thereof, touching
public or private interests in invaded countries. Restitution of
Russian and Roumanian gold yielded to Germany or taken by that
Power. This gold to be delivered in trust to the Allies until
signature of peace.'
- It is to be noticed, in passing, that they contain nothing
which limits the damage to damage inflicted contrary to the
recognised rules of warfare. That is to say, it is permissible to
include claims arising out of the legitimate capture of a
merchantman at sea, as well as the costs of illegal submarine
warfare.
- Mark-paper or mark-credits owned in ex-occupied territory by
Allied nationals should be included, if at all, in the settlement
of enemy debts, along with other sums owed to Allied nationals,
and not in connection with reparation.
- A special claim on behalf of Belgium was actually included in
the peace treaty, and was accepted by the German representatives
without demur.
- To the British observer, one scene, however, stood out
distinguished from the rest -- the field of Ypres. In that
desolate and ghostly spot, the natural colour and humours of the
landscape and the climate seemed designed to express to the
traveller the memories of the ground. A visitor to the salient
early in November 1918, when a few German bodies still added a
touch of realism and human horror, and the great struggle was not
yet certainly ended, could feel there, as nowhere else, the
present outrage of war, and at the same time the tragic and
sentimental purification which to the future will in some degree
transform its harshness.
- These notes, estimated to amount to no less than six thousand
million marks, are now a source of embarrassment and great
potential loss to the Belgian government, inasmuch as on their
recovery of the country they took them over from their nationals
in exchange for Belgian notes at the rate of Fr. 1.20 = Mk. 1.
This rate of exchange, being substantially in excess of the value
of the mark-notes at the rate of exchange current at the time
(and enormously in excess of the rate to which the mark-notes
have since fallen, the Belgian franc being now worth more than
three marks), was the occasion of the smuggling of mark-notes
into Belgium on an enormous scale, to take advantage of the
profit obtainable. The Belgian government took this very
imprudent step partly because they hoped to persuade the peace
conference to make the redemption of these bank-notes, at the par
of exchange, a first charge on German assets. The peace
conference held, however, that reparation proper must take
precedence of the adjustment of improvident banking transactions
effected at an excessive rate of exchange. The possession by the
Belgian government of this great mass of German currency, in
addition to an amount of nearly two thousand million marks held
by the French government which they similarly exchanged for the
benefit of the population of the invaded areas and of
Alsace-Lorraine, is a serious aggravation of the exchange
position of the mark. It will certainly be desirable for the
Belgian and German governments to come to some arrangement as to
its disposal, though this is rendered difficult by the prior lien
held by the reparation commission over all German assets
available for such purposes.
- It should be added, in fairness, that the very high claims put
forward on behalf of Belgium generally include not only
devastation proper, but all kinds of other items, as, for
example, the profits and earnings which Belgians might reasonably
have expected to earn if there had been no war.
- 'The wealth and income of the chief Powers', by J. C. Stamp
(Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, July 1919).
- Other estimates vary from £2,420 million to £2,680 million.
See Stamp, loc. cit.
- This was clearly and courageously pointed out by M. Charles
Gide in L'Emancipation for February 1919.
- For details of these and other figures, see Stamp, loc. cit.
- Even when the extent of the material damage has been
established, it will be exceedingly difficult to put a price on
it, which must largely depend on the period over which
restoration is spread, and the methods adopted. It would be
impossible to make the damage good in a year or two at any price,
and an attempt to do so at a rate which was excessive in relation
to the amount of labour and materials at hand might force prices
up to almost any level. We must, I think, assume a cost of labour
and materials about equal to that current in the world generally.
In point of fact, however, we may safely assume that literal
restoration will never be attempted. Indeed, it would be very
wasteful to do so. Many of the townships were old and unhealthy,
and many of the hamlets miserable. To re-erect the same type of
building in the same places would be foolish. As for the land,
the wise course may be in some cases to leave long strips of it
to Nature for many years to come. An aggregate money sum should
be computed as fairly representing the value of the material
damage, and France should be left to expend it in the manner she
thinks wisest with a view to her economic enrichment as a whole.
The first breeze of this controversy has already blown through
France. A long and inconclusive debate occupied the Chamber
during the spring of 1919, as to whether inhabitants of the
devastated area receiving compensation should be compelled to
expend it in restoring the identical property, or whether they
should be free to use it as they like. There was evidently a
great deal to be said on both sides; in the former case there
would be much hardship and uncertainty for owners who could not,
many of them, hope to recover the effective use of their property
perhaps for years to come, and yet would not be free to set
themselves up elsewhere; on the other hand, if such persons were
allowed to take their compensation and go elsewhere, the
countryside of northern France would never be put right.
Nevertheless I believe that the wise course will be to allow
great latitude and let economic motives take their own course.
- La Richesse de la France devant la Guerre, published in 1916.
- Revue Bleue, 3 February 1919. This is quoted in a very
valuable selection of French estimates and expressions of
opinion, forming chapter iv of La Liquidation financière de la
Guerre, by H. Charriaut and R. Hacault. The general magnitude of
my estimate is further confirmed by the extent of the repairs
already effected, as set forth in a speech delivered by M.
Tardieu on 10 October 1919, in which he said: 'On 16 September
last, of 2,246 kilometres of railway track destroyed, 2,016 had
been repaired; of 1,075 kilometres of canal, 700; of 1,160
constructions, such as bridges and tunnels, which had been blown
up, 588 had been replaced; of 550,000 houses ruined by
bombardment, 60,000 had been rebuilt; and of 1,800,000 hectares
of ground rendered useless by battle, 400,000 had been
recultivated, 200,000 hectares of which are now ready to be sown.
Finally, more than 10,000,000 metres of barbed wire had been
removed.'
- Some of these estimates include allowance for contingent and
immaterial damage as well as for direct material injury.
- A substantial part of this was lost in the service of the
Allies; this must not be duplicated by inclusion both in their
claims and in ours.
- The fact that no separate allowance is made in the above for
the sinking of 675 fishing vessels of 71,765 tons gross, or for
the 1,885 vessels of 8,007,967 tons damaged or molested, but not
sunk, may be set off against what may be an excessive figure for
replacement cost.
- The losses of the Greek mercantile marine were excessively
high, as a result of the dangers of the Mediterranean; but they
were largely incurred on the service of the other Allies, who
paid for them directly or indirectly. The claims of Greece for
maritime losses incurred on the service of her own nationals
would not be very considerable.
- There is a reservation in the peace treaty on this question.
'The Allied and Associated Powers formally reserve the right of
Russia to obtain from Germany restitution and reparation based on
the principles of the present treaty' (article 116).
- Dr Diouritch in his 'Economic and statistical survey of the
southern Slav nations' (Journal of the Royal Statistical Society,
May 1919), quotes some extraordinary figures of the loss of life:
'According to the official returns, the number of those fallen in
battle or died in captivity up to the last Serbian offensive
amounted to 320,000, which means that one-half of Serbia's male
population, from 18 to 60 years of age, perished outright in the
European war. In addition, the Serbian medical authorities
estimate that about 300,000 people have died from typhus among
the civil population, and the losses among the population
interned in enemy camps are estimated at 50,000. During the two
Serbian retreats and during the Albanian retreat the losses among
children and young people are estimated at 200,000. Lastly,
during over three years of enemy occupation, the losses in lives
owing to the lack of proper food and medical attention are
estimated at 250,000.' Altogether, he puts the losses in life at
above a million, or more than one-third of the population of Old
Serbia.
- Come si calcola e a quanto ammonta la richezza d'Iialia e
delle altre principali nazioni, published in 1919.
- Very large claims put forward by the Serbian authorities
include many hypothetical items of indirect and non-material
damage; but these, however real, are not admissible under our
present formula.
- Assuming that in her case £250 million are included for the
general expenses of the war defrayed out of loans made to Belgium
by her allies.
- It must be said to Mr Hughes' honour that he apprehended from
the first the bearing of the pre-armistice negotiations on our
right to demand an indemnity covering the full costs of the war,
protested against our ever having entered into such engagements,
and maintained loudly that he had been no party to them and could
not consider himself bound by them. His indignation may have been
partly due to the fact that Australia, not having been ravaged,
would have no claims at all under the more limited interpretation
of our rights.
- The whole cost of the war has been estimated at from £24,000
million upwards. This would mean an annual payment of interest
(apart from sinking fund) of £1,200 million. Could any expert
committee have reported that Germany can pay this sum?
- But unhappily they did not go down with their flags flying
very gloriously. For one reason or another their leaders
maintained substantial silence. What a different position in the
country's estimation they might hold now if they had suffered
defeat amidst firm protests against the fraud, chicane, and
dishonour of the whole proceedings.
- Only after the most painful consideration have I written
these words. The almost complete absence of protest from the
leading statesmen of England makes one feel that one must have
made some mistake. But I believe that I know all the facts, and I
can discover no such mistake. In any case, I have set forth all
the relevant engagements in chapter 4 and at the beginning of
this chapter, so that the reader can form his own judgment.
- In conversation with Frenchmen who were private persons and
quite unaffected by political considerations, this aspect became
very clear. You might persuade them that some current estimates
as to the amount to be got out of Germany were quite fantastic.
Yet at the end they would always come back to where they had
started: 'But Germany must pay; for, otherwise, what is to happen
to France?'
- A further paragraph claims the war costs of Belgium 'in
accordance with Germany's pledges, already given, as to complete
restoration for Belgium'.
- The challenge of the other Allies, as well as of the enemy,
had to be met; for in view of the limited resources of the
latter, the other Allies had perhaps a greater interest than the
enemy in seeing that no one of their number established an
excessive claim.
- M. Klotz has estimated the French claims on this head at
£3,000 million (75 milliard francs, made up of 13 milliard for
allowances, 60 for pensions, and 2 for widows). If this figure is
correct, the others should probably be scaled up also.
- That is to say, I claim for the aggregate figure an accuracy
within 25%.
- In his speech of 5 September 1919, addressed to the French
Chamber, M. Klotz estimated the total Allied claims against
Germany under the treaty at £15,000 million, which would
accumulate at interest until 1921, and be paid off thereafter by
34 annual instalments of about £1,000 million each, of which
France would receive about £550 million annually. 'The general
effect of the statement (that France would receive from Germany
this annual payment) proved', it is reported, 'appreciably
encouraging to the country as a whole, and was immediately
reflected in the improved tone on the Bourse and throughout the
business world in France.' So long as such statements can be
accepted in Paris without protest, there can be no financial or
economic future for France, and a catastrophe of disillusion is
not far distant.
- As a matter of subjective judgment, I estimate for this
figure an accuracy of 10% in deficiency and 20% in excess, i.e.,
that the result will lie between £6,400 million and £8,800
million.
- Germany is also liable under the treaty, as an addition to
her liabilities for reparation, to pay all the costs of the
armies of occupation after peace is signed for the fifteen
subsequent years of occupation. So far as the text of the treaty
goes, there is nothing to limit the size of these armies, and
France could, therefore, by quartering the whole of her normal
standing army in the occupied area, shift the charge from her own
taxpayers to those of Germany -- though in reality any such
policy would be at the expense not of Germany, who by hypothesis
is already paying for reparation up to the full limit of her
capacity, but of France's allies, who would receive so much less
in respect of reparation. A White Paper (Cmd. 240) has, however,
been issued, in which is published a declaration by the
governments of the United States, Great Britain, and France
engaging themselves to limit the sum payable annually by Germany
to cover the cost of occupation to £12 million, 'as soon as the
Allied and Associated Powers concerned are convinced that the
conditions of disarmament by Germany are being satisfactorily
fulfilled'. The three Powers reserve to themselves the liberty
to modify this arrangement at any time if they agree that it is
necessary.
- Article 235. The force of this article is somewhat
strengthened by article 251, by virtue of which dispensations may
also be granted for 'other payments' as well as for food and raw
material.
- This is the effect of paragraph 12 (c) of annex II of the
reparation chapter, leaving minor complications on one side. The
treaty fixes the payments in terms of gold marks, which are
converted in the above at the rate of 20 to £1.
- If, per impossibile, Germany discharged £500 million in cash
or kind by 1921, her annual payments would be at the rate of
£62,500,000 from 1921 to 1925 and of £150 million thereafter
- Paragraph 16 of annex II of the reparation chapter. There is
also an obscure provision by which interest may be charged 'on
sums arising out of material damage as from 11 November 1918 up
to 1 May 1921'. This seems to differentiate damage to property
from damage to the person in favour of the former. It does not
affect pensions and allowances, the cost of which is capitalised
as at the date of the coming into force of the treaty.
- On the assumption which no one supports and even the most
optimistic fear to be unplausible, that Germany can pay the full
charge for interest and siding fund from the outset, the annual
payment would amount to £480 million.
- Under paragraph 13 of annex II unanimity is required (i) for
any postponement beyond 1930 of instalments due between 1921 and
1926, and (ii) for any postponement for more than three years of
instalments due after 1926. Further, under article 234, the
commission may not cancel any part of the indebtedness without
the specific authority of all the governments represented on the
commission.
- On 23 July 1914 the amount was £67,800,000.
- Owing to the very high premium which exists on German silver
coin, as the combined result of the depreciation of the mark and
the appreciation of silver, it is highly improbable that it will
be possible to extract such coin out of the pockets of the
people. But it may gradually leak over the frontier by the agency
of private speculators, and thus indirectly benefit the German
exchange position as a whole.
- The Allies made the supply of foodstuffs to Germany during
the armistice, mentioned above, conditional on the provisional
transfer to them of the greater part of the mercantile marine, to
be operated by them for the purpose of shipping foodstuffs to
Europe generally, and to Germany in particular. The reluctance of
the Germans to agree to this was productive of long and dangerous
delays in the supply of food, but the abortive conferences of
Trèves and Spa (16 January, 14-16 February, and 4–5 March 1919)
were at last followed by the agreement of Brussels (14 March
1919). The unwillingness of the Germans to conclude was mainly
due to the lack of any absolute guarantee on the part of the
Allies that, if they surrendered the ships, they would get the
food. But assuming reasonable good faith on the part of the
latter (their behaviour in respect of certain other clauses of
the armistice, however, had not been impeccable and gave the
enemy some just grounds for suspicion), their demand was not an
improper one; for without the German ships the business of
transporting the food would have been difficult, if not
impossible, and the German ships surrendered or their equivalent
were in fact almost wholly employed in transporting food to
Germany itself. Up to 30 June 1919, 176 German ships of 1,025,388
gross tonnage had been surrendered to the Allies in accordance
with the Brussels agreement.
- The amount of tonnage transferred may be rather greater and
the value per ton rather less. The aggregate value involved is
not likely, however, to be less than £100 million or greater than
£150 million.
- This census was carried out by virtue of a decree of 23
August 1916. On 22 March 1917, the German government acquired
complete control over the utilisation of foreign securities in
German possession; and in May 1917 it began to exercise these
powers for the mobilisation of certain Swedish, Danish, and Swiss
securities.
£ (million)
1892. Schmoller 500
1892. Christians 650
1893-4. Koch 600
1905. v. Halle 800(ß)
1913. Helfferich 1,000(þ)
1914. Ballod 1,250
1914. Pistorius 1,250
1919. Hans David 1,050(Å)
ß. Plus £500 million for investments other than securities.
þ Net investments, i.e. after allowance for property in Germany
owned abroad. This may also be the case with some of the other
estimates.
Å This estimate, given in Weltwirtschaftszeitung (13 June 1919),
is an estimate of the value of Germany's foreign investments as
at the outbreak of war.
- I have made no deduction for securities in the ownership of
Alsace-Lorrainers and others who have now ceased to be German
nationals.
- In all these estimates I am conscious of being driven, by a
fear of overstating the case against the treaty, into giving
figures in excess of my own real judgment. There is a great
difference between putting down on paper fancy estimates of
Germany's resources and actually extracting contributions in the
form of cash. I do not myself believe that the reparation
commission will secure real resources from the above items by May
1921 even as great as the lower of the two figures given above.
- The treaty (see article 114) leaves it very dubious how far
the Danish government is under an obligation to make payments to
the reparation commission in respect of its acquisition of
Schleswig. They might, for instance, arrange for various offsets
such as the value of the mark-notes held by the inhabitants of
ceded areas. In any case the amount of money involved is quite
small. The Danish government is raising a loan for £6,600,000
(kr. 120,000,000) for the joint purposes of 'taking over
Schleswig's share of the German debt, for buying German public
property, for helping the Schleswig population, and for settling
the currency question'.
- Here again my own judgment would carry me much further and I
should doubt the possibility of Germany's exports equalling her
imports during this period. But the statement in the text goes
far enough for the purpose of my argument.
- It has been estimated that the cession of territory to
France, apart from the loss of Upper Silesia, may reduce
Germany's annual pre-war production of steel ingots from 20
million tons to 14 million tons, and increase France's capacity
from 5 million tons to 11 million tons.
- Germany's exports of sugar in 1913 amounted to 1,110,073 tons
of the value of £13,094,300, of which 838,583 tons were exported
to the United Kingdom at a value of £9,050,800. These figures
were in excess of the normal, the average total exports for the
five years ending 1913 being about £10 million.
- The necessary price adjustment which is required on both
sides of this account will be made en bloc later.
- If the amount of the sinking fund be reduced, and the annual
payment is continued over a greater number of years, the present
value -- so powerful is the operation of compound interest --
cannot be materially increased. A payment of £100 million
annually in perpetuity, assuming interest, as before, at 5%,
would only raise the present value to £2,000 million.
- As an example of public misapprehension on economic affairs,
the following letter from Sir Sidney Low to The Times of 3
December 1918 deserves quotation: 'I have seen authoritative
estimates which place the gross value of Germany's mineral and
chemical resources as high as £250,000 million sterling or even
more; and the Ruhr basin mines alone are said to be worth over
£45,000 million. It is certain, at any rate, that the capital
value of these natural supplies is much greater than the toil war
debts of all the Allied states. Why should not some portion of
this wealth be diverted for a sufficient period from its present
owners and assigned to the peoples whom Germany has assailed,
deported, and injured? The Allied governments might justly
require Germany to surrender to them the use of such of her mines
and mineral deposits as would yield, say, from 100 to 200
millions annually for the next 30, 40, or 50 years. By this means
we could obtain sufficient compensation from Germany without
unduly stimulating her manufactures and export trade to our
detriment.' It is not clear why, if Germany has wealth exceeding
£250,000 million sterling, Sir Sidney Low is content with the
trifling sum of 100 to 200 millions annually. But his letter is
an admirable reductio ad absurdum of a certain line of thought.
While a mode of calculation which estimates the value of coal
miles deep in the bowels of the earth as high as in a coal
scuttle, of an annual lease of £1,000 for 999 years at £999,000
and of a field (presumably) at the value of all the crops it will
grow to the end of recorded time, opens up great possibilities,
it is also double-edged. If Germany's total resources are worth
£250,000 million, those she will part with in the cession of
Alsace-Lorraine and Upper Silesia should be more than sufficient
to pay the entire costs of the war and reparation together. In
point of fact, the present market value of all the mines in
Germany of every kind has been estimated at £300 million, or a
little more than one-thousandth part of Sir Sidney Low's
expectations.
- The conversion at par of 5,000 million marks overstates by
reason of the existing depreciation of the mark, the present
money burden of the actual pensions payments, but not, in all
probability, the real loss of national productivity as a result
of the casualties suffered in the war.
- It cannot be overlooked, in passing, that in its results on a
country's surplus productivity a lowering of the standard of life
acts both ways. Moreover, we are without experience of the
psychology of a white race under conditions little short of
servitude. It is, however, generally supposed that if the whole
of a man's surplus production is taken from him, his efficiency
and his industry are diminished. The entrepreneur and the
inventor will not contrive, the trader and shopkeeper will not
save, the labourer will not toil, if the fruits of their industry
are set aside, not for the benefit of their children, their old
age, their pride, or their position, but for the enjoyment of a
foreign conqueror.
- In the course of the compromises and delays of the
conference, there were many questions on which, in order to reach
any conclusion at all, it was necessary to leave a margin of
vagueness and uncertainty. The whole method of the conference
tended towards this -- the Council of Four wanted, not so much a
settlement, as a treaty. On political and territorial questions
the tendency was to leave the final arbitrament to the League of
Nations. But on financial and economic questions the final
decision has generally been left with the reparation commission,
in spite of its being an executive body composed of interested
parties.
- The sum to be paid by Austria for reparation is left to the
absolute discretion of the reparation commission, no determinate
figure of any kind being mentioned in the text of the treaty.
Austrian questions are to be handled by a special section of the
reparation commission, but the section will have no powers except
such as the main commission may delegate.
- Bulgaria is to pay an indemnity of £90 million by half-yearly
instalments, beginning 1 July 1920. These sums will be collected,
on behalf of the reparation commission, by an inter-Ally
commission of control, with its seat at Sofia. In some respects
the Bulgarian inter-Ally commission appears to have powers and
authority independent of the reparation commission, but it is to
act, nevertheless, as the agent of the later, and is authorised
to tender advice to the reparation commission as to, for example,
the reduction of the half-yearly instalments.
- Under the treaty this is the function of any body appointed
for the purpose by the principal Allied and Associated
governments, and not necessarily of the reparation commission.
But it may be presumed that no second body will be established
for this special purpose.
- At the date of writing no treaties with these countries have
been drafted. It is possible that Turkey might be dealt with by a
separate commission.
- This appears to me to be in effect the position (if this
paragraph means anything at all), in spite of the following
disclaimer of such intentions in the Allies' reply: 'Nor does
paragraph 12 (b) of annex II give the commission powers to
prescribe or enforce taxes or to dictate the character of the
German budget.'
- Whatever that may mean.
- Assuming that the capital sum is discharged evenly over a
period as short as thirty-three years, this has the effect of
halving the burden as compared with the payments required on the
basis of 5% interest on the outstanding capital.
- I forbear to outline further details of the German offer as
the above are the essential points.
- For this reason it is not strictly comparable with my
estimate of Germany's capacity in an earlier section of this
chapter, which estimate is on the basis of Germany's condition as
it will be when the rest of the treaty has come into effect.
- Owing to delays on the part of the Allies in ratifying the
treaty, the reparation commission had not yet been formally
constituted by the end of October 1919. So far as I am aware,
therefore, nothing has been done to make the above offer
effective. But perhaps, in view of the circumstances, there has
been an extension of the date.
<< 4: The Treaty || 6: Europe After the Treaty >>
|